analyze the specific legal case, and then illustrate the possible policy implications of the analysis
Each student is expected to write an essay of no more or 1000 words on one among ten possible application of the course material and illustrated in the last class. The proposal should highlight how the course material can be used to analyze the specific legal case, and then illustrate the possible policy implications of the analysis
presention points
models
1. The Weakness of Shareholders Protection.
2. Property Rights and Financial Inefficiencies.
3. Property Rights and Market Power.
4. Property Rights and Lemons-type Distortions.
5. Property Rights and Incomplete Contracting Costs.
6. Genetic Diversity.
7. Adverse Possession.
8. Property Private.
9. Property Market.
10. Property Professional.
11. Property Auction.
12. Good Faith.
13. Culture.
14. Enforcement.
Property Rights, Transaction Costs,
and the Limits of the Market.∗
Carmine Guerriero
University of Bologna
August 18, 2017
Abstract
Although the relevance of property rights and transaction costs for trade and inno- vation has been longly discussed, we still lack a formal framework to think about their origins and interplay. Within trade interactions, fully protecting the original owners’ property implies that some high-valuation potential buyers inefficiently refuse to buy it because of transaction costs. When instead property rights are weak, low-valuation potential buyers inefficiently expropriate the original owners’ property. The trade-off between these two misallocations entails that property rights will be weaker the larger transaction costs are regardless of whether they are driven by frictions outside the control of traders/innovators or determined by the mix of the dispersion the traders’ valuations and either the original owners’ market power or their privileged information. A similar conclusion holds true for an upstream firm’s property rights on an input nec- essary to a downstream firm to introduce a new technology and whose cost is random and ex ante non contractible. This time, transaction costs rise with the likelihood that the new technology is more productive. All these implications survive when a minority of traders/innovators has a larger political influence on institutional design and when the disincentive to effort effect of weak property rights is taken into account. Crucially, the model predictions are consistent with the negative effects of proxies for market fric- tions and failures on measures of the protection of personal, intellectual, and financial property for a panel of 135 countries spanning the 2006-2015 period. Evidence from several identification strategies suggests that these relationships are causal. Keywords: Property Rights; Transaction Costs; Market Frictions; Market Failures. JEL classification: D23; L11; P14; Z10.
∗I would like to thank Andy Hanssen, Oliver Hart, Raffaella Paduano, and Giorgio Zanarone for insightful comments. Address: Strada Maggiore 45, 40125 Bologna, Italy. E-mail: c.guerriero@unibo.it
“Whenever transactions [. . .] are very expensive, [. . .] coercion is inherent [and] society will pick the
entitlement it deems favorable to the general welfare” [Calabresi and Melamed 1972, p. 1101].
“As soon as the land of any country has all become private property, the landlords, like all other men,
love to reap where they never sowed, and demand a rent even for its natural produce” [Smith 1976, p. 67].
1 Introduction
Albeit overwhelming evidence shows that strong property rights foster trade and innova-
tion, only recently economists have begun to study the determinants of this institution by
looking at the trade-off between the dispersed coercive power in a state of anarchy and the
predation by a central enforcement authority (Besley and Ghatak, 2010). Here, I qualify
these contributions by incorporating into the economics literature the key insight proposed by
an enormous legal scholarship (Calabresi and Melamed, 1972) and, notably, that incomplete
property rights can be efficient when transaction costs impede economic activities.
To characterize the trade-off between inefficient exclusion from trade/innovation and ex-
propriation guiding property rights selection, I study both the possibly consensual exchange
of economic value between its original owner and a potential buyer and a downstream firm’s
choice of whether to produce in-house through an old technology or to adopt a new one ne-
cessitating an upstream firm’s input. In the former case, I build on Guerriero (2016a), and I
study a society equally split into original owners, who have the same valuation for the only
good in the economy, and potential buyers, who are instead endowed with heterogeneous
valuations. The former are randomly matched to the latter by an intermediation technology
that allows each potential buyer to either obtain the good via consensual transfer by paying
the original owner’s valuation and bearing socially wasteful transaction costs or expropriate
it at no cost. I define property rights as the probability that an expropriated good is given
back to its original owner. When property is fully protected, some potential buyers with
valuation higher than that of the original owners are inefficiently excluded from trade due to
transaction costs. When instead the protection of property is weak, low-valuation potential
buyers inefficiently expropriate original owners. The trade-off between these two misalloca-
tions entails that the protection of property, and thus the size of the market, will be more
2
limited the larger transaction costs are, regardless of whether they are driven by frictions
outside the control of traders/innovators—e.g., financial inefficiencies—or endogenously de-
termined by the mix of the dispersion the traders’ valuations and either the original owners’
market power or their privileged information. The same conclusion can be reached when I
analyze investment interactions in a society equally split into randomly matched downstream
and upstream firms. The new technology requires upfront expenses by the downstream firm
and the provision by the upstream firm of an input whose cost is random. While both costs
and the firms’ payoffs are observable, unverifiable, and ex ante non contractible, only the
cost of the input is ex post contractible. Without loss of generality in particular, I maintain
that after the preliminary phase the upstream firm has all the bargaining power and so tries
to hold-up his match by asking the high-cost realization. The downstream firm can then
either accept to pay the inflated cost, switch to the old technology, or turn to the legal
system. In the last case, the payoffs are determined by the upstream firms’ property rights,
which capture now the odds with which the downstream firm must accept the high cost.
This assumption squares with the idea that courts exploit unverifiable information to favor
the party they prefer regardless of the contract terms (Gennaioli, 2013). When the protec-
tion of property is strong, the risk of being held-up discourages the downstream firms from
innovating. When instead the upstream firms are only weakly protected, low-productivity
downstream firms inefficiently exploit the input. Balancing these two misallocations entails
that the protection of property rights (size of the market) will be weaker (larger) the greater
incomplete contracting costs are, i.e., the higher is the probability of low-cost realization.
Crucially, all the model implications survive when a minority of traders/innovators has
a larger political influence on institutional design and when the disincentive to effort effect
of weak property rights is taken into account, and they apply to a wider range of cases. To
elaborate on the last point, the legal expropriation by a potential buyer (downstream firm)
is strategically similar to a condoned squatting of either a land or a building, the compulsory
licensing granted to an intellectual property infringer, a majority stockholder’s legal capacity
to tunnel creditors’ and minority shareholders’ resources out of a firm, and the discretion of
a principal to lawfully segment a labor, financial, or even housing market (the tunneling by
a majority stockholder and an agent’s power to successfully breach a contract).
3
To evaluate the central model prediction, I analyze a panel of 135 countries for which
the Executive Opinion Survey—EOS, hereafter—run by the World Economic Forum report
measures of the protection of personal, intellectual, and financial property and proxies for
transaction costs between 2006 and 2015 (see table 1). The EOS is the longest-running
survey of the opinions of business leaders on a broad range of topics for which statistics are
unreliable, outdated, or nonexistent (WEF, 2015).1 Starting with the metrics of property
rights, I consider three indicators ranging between one and seven and gaging respectively the
protection of generic property including financial assets—Property-Rights, the defense of in-
tellectual property rights including anti-counterfeiting measures—Intellectual-Property, and
the safeguard of the interests of minority shareholders—Shareholders-Protection (see table 2
for the definition and sources of these and the remaining variables used in the present study).
Being these rights typically assigned to the downstream firms providing the main productive
resources [Burk and McDonnel 2007, p. 594], the three aforementioned indexes constitute
an inverse (direct) metrics of the property rights of the upstream (downstream) firms. The
maps in figure 1 visualize the strong correlation among these three measures—nowhere lower
than 0.81—and their sizable variation across countries. To draw these maps, I averaged each
variable over time, and then I divided the range of each average into four equal intervals. In
the empirical test instead, I use the continuously measured yearly variables. Furthermore,
I document in the Internet appendix that the evidence remains essentially the same when I
consider a measure of adverse possession of personal property,2 which however has no time
variation (Dari-Mattiacci and Guerriero, 2015). Turning to the proxies for transaction costs,
I consider measures of the severity of both market frictions—i.e., excessive regulation and
financial inefficiencies—and failures, i.e., lack of the competitiveness of corporate activity,
lemons-type distortions, and incomplete contracting costs due to asset specificities.
Ordinary least squares—OLS—estimates suggest that the protection of personal, intel-
lectual, and financial property is the weakest (strongest) where market frictions and failures
(asset specificities) are the largest. Albeit strongly consistent with the main model implica-
1The 2015 edition gathered more than 14,000 responses in 144 countries (WEF, 2015). I substitute missing observations with the closest data points. This choice is immaterial to the gist of the analysis.
2This is a form of property rights acquisition such that a possessor becomes the legal owner of a good without the original owner’s consent, but by virtue of a sufficiently long, open, continuous, and notorious possession.
4
tions, these results may be capturing reverse causality, may be driven by the confounding
effect of omitted variables, or may be attenuated by the error in the measurement of trans-
action costs. Accordingly, I pursue a number of strategies to determine if the correlations
I uncover are, in fact, causal. First, I control not only for fixed country and year effects,
but also for the development level, the inclusiveness of political institutions, the level of
nonproduced output, external and internal conflicts, and human capital. Considering these
observables together leaves the results almost intact. Second, I use recent insights from Al-
tonji, Elder, and Taber (2005) to calculate how much greater the influence of unobservable
factors, relative to observables, would need to be to explain away the negative links between
property rights and transaction costs. I find that the influence of unobservables would have
to be on average sixty times greater than that of all observables considered together, which
seems unlikely. Finally, I devise a 2SLS approach based on the positive dependence of mar-
ket frictions and failures (incomplete contracting) on the dispersion in the traders’ valuation
(productivity of the available technologies) foreseen by the model. To elaborate, I document
strong negative first-stages between transaction costs and proxies for both the availability
of the latest technology and the quality of math and science education. These results are
consistent with recent firm-level evidence suggesting that the distance to the technological
frontier—and thus the difference in the desirability of old and new products and in the
productivity of the available technologies—is smaller in countries endowed with a human
capital more apt to absorb ideas and knowledge (see Añón Higón et al., [2017]). Conditional
on all observables, the 2SLS estimates are very similar to the OLS ones, and the validity
of the exclusion restriction is vindicated by the two extra pieces of evidence. First, the
Kleibergen-Paap test always rejects that the estimated equation is under-identified at the 1
percent or less. Second, the overidentifying restrictions cannot be rejected at a level nowhere
lower than 5 percent, and the excluded instruments have no direct impact on property rights
in the semi-reduced form regressions. All in all, these robustness checks make it difficult
to envision that OLS correlations are spuriously driven by reverse causation, a mechanism
different from the one I model, or measurement error. Accordingly, I take them as consistent
with, if not proving, causality running from transaction costs to property rights.
The present study is strictly related to several strands of literature. First, a legacy
5
of recent contributions shows that weak property rights can be optimal in an endowment
economy (Jordan, 2006; Piccione and Rubinstein, 2007; Bar-Gill and Persico, 2016; Segal
and Whinston, 2016; Arruñada, Zanarone, and Garoupa, 2017). Not only do I extend this
result to production economies by clarifying how weak property rights can curb market
frictions and partially solve market failures,3 but I also highlight the relationships between
the latter and either the dispersion in the traders’ valuations and in the productivity of the
available technologies. Accordingly, my analysis is also related to a body of research—still
in its infancy—on endogenous transaction costs (Dari-Mattiacci, 2012; Barry, Hatfield, and
Kominers, 2014).4 Finally, Acemoglu and Johnson (2005) focus on the relative importance of
protecting property rights and enforcing contracts, whereas I examine the determinants of the
trade-off between these two institutional strategies created by the possibility of transferring
value without consent (see also Dari-Mattiacci and Guerriero, [2015]). Differently from this
contribution moreover, I also emphasize that weak property rights are society’s response to
the existence of sizable transaction costs and thus their negative correlation with economic
outcomes might be partly spurious (see for a similar argument Aghion et al., [2010]).
The paper proceeds as follows. In section 2, I discuss the basic relationships between
property rights and transaction costs to motivate my more general model, which I illustrate
in section 3. Next, I assess whether these correlations are indeed causal in section 4. Finally,
I conclude in section 5, and I gather the proofs, tables, and figures in the appendix.
2 Property Rights and Transaction Costs
While all legal systems punish theft and embezzlement and provide remedies for the
dispossessed owners, the protection of property against private expropriation is almost never
complete as clearly displayed in the maps in figure 1. When transaction costs are sizable
indeed, a private party is often allowed to take someone else’s property with or without
paying compensation (Bouckaert and De Geest, 1995). To cast a first glance at whether this
pattern accurately describes also the EOS data, I consider indexes ranging between one and
3Albeit based on the same basic model, Guerriero (2016a) focuses instead on the relationship between property rights and the heterogeneity in the potential buyers’ valuations and does not consider either the issue of technology adoption or the related problem of identifying the drivers of incomplete contracting costs.
4While the former emphasizes the feedback of legal rules on transaction costs, the latter draw a link between transaction costs and how egalitarian is the distribution of the collective gains from Coasean bargaining.
6
seven and capturing the severity of financial inefficiencies and the relevance of each of the
market failures analyzed in the model below, i.e., lack of the competitiveness of corporate
activity, lemons-type distortions, and incomplete contracting costs due to asset specificities.
Starting with the first one, I consider an index measuring the financial sector difficulties
in providing products and services to businesses—Unavailability-Financing. A value of one
suggests that the financial sector provides a wide variety, whereas a value of seven implies
that it does not provide them at all. For what concerns market power, I consider an index
capturing the competitiveness of corporate activity—Market-Dominance. A value of one
suggests that corporate activity is spread among many firms, whereas a value of one implies
that it is dominated by few business groups. Turning to lemons-type distortions, I focus on
an index falling with the extent of information used by buyers to make purchasing decisions—
Asymmetric-Information. A value of one suggests that purchases are based on a sophisticated
analysis of attributes, whereas a value of seven implies that they are based solely on the lowest
price. Finally to capture asset specificities, I consider an index measuring the competitive
advantage of the country’s companies in international markets—Asset-Specificities. A value
of one suggests that it is represented by low cost labor or natural resources, whereas a value
of seven implies that it is constituted by unique products and processes.
Conditional on fixed country and year effects, the partial correlations between the mea-
sures of property rights and Unavailability-Financing, Market-Dominance, and Asymmetric-
Information (Asset-Specificities) in figures 2 to 4 (figure 5) reveal that there are strong
negative (positive) links between the legal protection of the original owners’ (downstream
firms’) property and market frictions and failures (asset specificities), which are not driven
by a handful of abnormal observations.5 Columns (2), (3), (5), and (6) of table 3 report
estimates of these correlation from regressions obtained from the subsamples for which I ob-
serve all the additional controls illustrated in section 4.1.1 and with standard errors allowing
for clustering by country. In particular, a one-standard-deviation increase in Unavailability-
Financing, Market-Dominance, and Asymmetric-Information (Asset-Specificities)—roughly
1 (0.9)—is associated with about a 0.3(0.4)-standard-deviation fall (rise) in the strength of
property rights, i.e., around 1. These coefficients are all significant at 5 percent or better and
5My results are similar when I exclude the outliers identified through the Cook’s distance (Cook 1977).
7
are coherent with the evidence coming from two alternative one-to-seven indexes of market
frictions and failures (see columns (1) and (4) of table 3). While the former gages the burden
of administrative requirements on firms—Over-Regulation, the latter measures the impact of
non-tariff barriers on the ability of imported goods to compete with domestic ones—Trade-
Barriers. More generally, I document in the Internet appendix that the negative (positive)
relationships between the original owners’ (downstream firms’) property rights and market
frictions and failures (asset specificities) survive when the latter are proxied by either the
necessity of bribery for the daily activity of firms, their difficulty to obtain a bank loan, the
hurdle they face when raising money by issuing shares on the stock market, or the lack of
competitiveness of local markets (the extent of production sophistication).
Next, I present a model of the design of property rights on exchangeable value and
innovation activities rationalizing several legal issues included the evidence discussed so far.
3 Theory
I first analyze the case in which transaction costs are driven by frictions outside the
control of traders/innovators, and then I turn to characterize the scenario in which they
are endogenously determined by the mix of the dispersion in the traders’ valuations and
either the original owners’ market power or their privileged information (the dispersion in
productivity of the available technologies and the incompleteness of contracts). Finally, I
document that the key model implications survive when the economy becomes “political”
and thus someone is excluded from the institutional design (see section 3.3.1) and when the
original owners can decide whether to produce or invest in their property (see section 3.3.2).
3.1 Property Rights and Exogenous Transaction Costs
Following Guerriero (2016a), I consider a society composed by a mass one of original
owners and a mass one of potential buyers, all having linear utility over a good x (see
footnote 13 for the risk aversion case). While the original owners value x at v, the potential
buyers have a valuation λ uniformly distributed over [ λ, λ ]
with l ≡ λ− λ, λ > v > λ, and
λm ≡ ( λ+ λ
) /2. I employ the uniform distribution to obtain closed form solutions, but in
the appendix I show that the results hold under more generic density functions.
8
Original owners are randomly matched to potential buyers by an intermediation tech-
nology that allows the latter to either obtain the good via consensual transfer by paying
the former v and bearing positive transaction costs α or expropriate it at no cost. The
assumption that expropriation is costless does not bear any loss of generality.6 α has no
social value and gages inefficiencies like the costs borne by the potential buyers to borrow v
or those necessary to legalize the transfer and due to excessive regulation and/or bribery.7
I posit that α < min { v, λ− v
} , and I discuss this assumption in footnotes 10, 11, and 12.
An expropriated x is returned back with probability γ, which thus summarizes the legal
protection of the original owner’s property rights or, in the Calabresi and Melamed’s (1972)
words, the odds with which the original owner is protected by a property rule as opposed to
1− γ, which is the chance with which the potential buyer is shielded by a liability rule.
One glaring example of the type of expropriation just discussed is that of an intermediary
(agent) selling to a buyer in good-faith a good stolen (embezzled) from an original owner (his
principal) at a low price. As happens in the model, then the good is possibly given back to
its original owner and the strength of property rights reduces the probability that the buyer
consumes. More generally, when the potential buyer directly steals x, only with probability
γ the legal system forces her to hand the good back to its original owner. All in all, then
γ will be larger the longer the buyer needs to wait before acquiring ownership by adverse
possession, the stronger are the remedies in the original owner’s hands, and the more effective
is public enforcement (Dari-Mattiacci and Guerriero, 2015). The model however applies to
a large array of legal instances. First, the good can be envisaged as an input producing a
fixed value when transformed via the “old” technology in the hands of the original owners
and an uncertain one when the “new” technology is applied by the potential buyers. Second,
expropriation can assume the form of the squatting of either a piece of land or a building
(Brueckner and Selod, 2009).8 Third, the conflict between an original owner and a potential
6The model implications survive when expropriation entails either an expensive effort or a punishment and if the liability rule prescribes positive damages, provided that these cost are not too large (Guerriero, 2016a).
7More generally, exogenous transaction costs can be represented by bargaining expenses or the mark-up imposed by a foreign intermediary. Notably, the setup I consider can be interpreted as an efficient market maker assigning high-valuation potential buyers to original owners in exchange for the wasteful payment α.
8The good can be conceived as having a fixed value for the original owner and an uncertain one for the state as in the instances regulated by “partial taking” law. Then, the state pays severance damages (1− γ) v to the original owner to compensate a partial expropriation by the potential buyer (Sackman at al., 2013).
9
buyer can be reinterpreted as the one involving the creator of an intellectual property and an
infringer with 1−γ being the chance of either exhaustion of the related rights or compulsory
licensing (Ghosh, 2014; Bond and Saggi, 2017). Fourth, the same tension is isomorphic to
that between a creditor/minority shareholder and a majority stockholder who can tunnel
resources out of the firm through a complaisant management (Johnson et al., 2000). Finally,
the very same interaction is strategically similar to that setting an agent against a principal
in a segmented labor, financial or housing market with 1− γ gaging the principal’s capacity
to lawfully operate in the secondary segment (Piazzesi, Schneider, and Stroebel, 2017).
At time t0, γ is chosen to maximize the social welfare, which is the sum of the original
owners’ and potential buyers’ utilities. At time t1, individuals learn who they are and,
thus, their valuation. At time t2, individuals are matched by the intermediation technology.
Finally at time t3, any expropriated x is given back to its original owner with probability γ.
In evaluating the foregoing, two remarks should be stressed. First, an alternative in-
strument in the hands of society is to decrease α. This policy reduces distortions leading to
complete property rights (see footnotes 10 and 11), but it is very costly to implement because
of political imperfections (Besley and Ghatak, 2010) and the opposition of those agents who
gain from larger transaction costs (see section 3.2 and Barry, Hatfield, and Kominers, [2014]).
Second, the model implication are unaffected when the original owners have heterogeneous
valuations and the traders can bargain over the price (see Guerriero [2016a]).
3.1.1 Equilibrium
A potential buyer buys if her valuation λ net of the purchasing costs v + α is greater
than her expected payoff from expropriation (1− γ)λ or λ ≥ λ̂ ≡ v+α γ
.9 When selecting the
optimal property rights level γ∗,10 society then maximizes the strictly concave function
∫ λ λ̂
λ− α l
dλ+
∫ λ̂ λ
(1− γ)λ+ γv l
dλ (1)
9Provided that only one good can be consumed, the results continue to stand even if those x that are purchased can be expropriated before consumption since all those willing to expropriate have already done it.
10The objective function in equation (1) is strictly concave for α < v. Should this inequality fail, γ∗ will be 1 (0)
for v < λm if the social welfare is larger at 1 (0) than it is at 0 (1) or whenever (v + α) 2−2
( αλ+ vλ
) +λ2 >
(≤)0. This last inequality is more difficult to satisfy the larger α is because of the hypothesis v + α < λ.
10
for λ̂ < λ or γ∗ ∈ ( v+α λ , 1 ]
and the social welfare under full expropriation (1− γ)λm + γv ≡
W FE otherwise. Switching from complete to incomplete property rights—i.e., from γ∗ = 1
to γ∗ < 1—has three effects: 1. it saves α at the cost of misallocating x with probability
γ∗ for the v + α ≤ λ < λ̂ matches; 2. it avoids misallocation with probability 1 − γ∗ for
the v ≤ λ < v + α matches by expanding the consumption set of the potential buyers; 3. it
misallocates x with probability 1−γ∗ for the λ < v matches. While this last effect is negative,
the sum of the first two is positive, provided that α is not too small.11 For λ̂ < λ, optimal
property rights are uniquely defined by the necessary and sufficient first-order condition
−2dλ̂ dγ
( γ∗λ̂− γ∗v − α
) − ( λ̂2 − λ2
) + 2v
( λ̂− λ
) = 0↔ (γ∗)2 = v
2 − α2
λ (2v − λ) . (2)
Equation (2) implies that a rise in γ has a marginal effect, which is positive, and an infra-
marginal effect ∫ λ̂ λ v−λ l dλ = −(λ̂−λ)(λ̂+λ−2v)
2l , which can be negative only if v < λm. For
v ≥ λm then, optimal property rights are complete since also W FE rises with γ. For v < λm instead, W FE falls with γ and a γ∗ ≤ 1 is possible. It equals either the level defined by
equation (2) or 0 depending on which of the two maximizes the social welfare. The latter is
more likely the case the larger α is.12 Moreover, an interior γ∗ falls with α (see figure 2).
Intuitively, a rise in α has the infra-marginal effect of reducing the potential buyer’s
payoff for all the λ ≥ λ̂ matches and the marginal effect of raising λ̂ and thus misallocating
goods otherwise earmarked to high-valuation potential buyers. The former effect prevails on
the latter, and thus property rights should be optimally weakened. Proposition 1 rephrases
this idea, which is the key result of the analysis of the exogenous transaction costs case:13
Proposition 1: The optimal property rights level γ∗ falls with the transaction costs α.
Proposition 1 is not only consistent with the preliminary evidence discussed in section 2
and the more in depth analysis in section 4, but it also sheds light on several institutionalized
cases of incomplete property rights. First, it rationalizes the post-war condoning of power
11Precisely, if α2 > (1− γ) v2. Moreover, γ∗ < 1 whenever α > v − λ, which can be given my assumptions. 12The exact condition is γ∗
( λ− v
) > α, which is true for the lowest interior γ∗ = (v + α)λ
−1 if α < λ− v.
13If risk-averse, the traders who gain an expected utility lower than that prevailing under the certain scenario of full property rights incur also a loss u. Since all original owners (potential buyers) weakly prefer complete (incomplete) property rights, a rise in risk aversion is isomorphic to a fall in v and thus induces a weakly lower γ∗. Indeed, an increase in v has the infra-marginal effect of boosting the original owners’ payoff when property rights are protected and the marginal effect of raising λ̂. Both patterns imply a higher γ∗.
11
thefts by Indian farmers. In fact, despite its annual cost is around 1.5 percentage points of the
2012 GDP, local politicians have been strenuously defending it by asserting that collecting the
electricity invoices, which are mainly constituted by billing costs, would destroy subsistence
farming (Charnoz and Swain, 2012). Second, the cost of eviction or the inability to provide a
sufficient supply of housing because of regulatory requirements and speculative land-holding
are the most recurring justifications to the tolerance towards the roughly 40 percent share of
private lands invaded in developing countries and the two billion squatters estimated around
the world (Brueckner and Selod, 2009). Third, exhaustion of intellectual property rights
has been mainly implemented in high-transaction costs developing countries (Ghosh, 2014),
whereas the Article 31 of the TRIPS agreement allows the participants to impose compulsory
licensing if the commercial terms for a voluntary license are “unreasonable” (Bond and Saggi,
2017). Finally, Piazzesi, Schneider, and Stroebel (2017) conclude that financial costs explain
14 percent of the price gap between first and secondary housing market segments.
3.2 Property Rights and Endogenous Transaction Costs
Next, I evaluate several key instances of endogenously determined transaction costs.
3.2.1 Property Rights and Market Power
Following Guerriero (2016a), I consider the case in which the intermediation technology
is in the hands of the original owners and α is the mark-up on their valuation v. They
select it between t1 and t2 by maximizing the sum of the expected profits and the expected
payoff from consuming x when handed back, i.e., (v+α)(λ−λ̂)
l +γ∗v
(λ̂−λ) l
for v+α γ∗
= λ̂ < λ and
γ∗v otherwise. Then, α∗ can be positive only for λ̂ < λ when it equals α∗ = γ∗(λ+v)
2 − v
and rises with the strength of property rights, which in turn increases the original owners’
payoff regardless of whether transfers are consensual. Turning to a rise in γ∗, it decreases
the potential buyers’ payoff from expropriating and, through the increase in α∗, their utility
from buying x. Because of the linearity of preferences, the two effects cancel out and dλ̂ dγ∗
= 0
(see the Appendix). Since α is now a transfer, γ∗ < 1 if the distortions in the potential
buyers’ demand are sizable. Being λ̂ = λ+v 2 < λ, society maximizes the linear function
∫ λ λ̂
λ
l dλ+
∫ λ̂ λ
(1− γ)λ+ γv l
dλ, (3)
12
whose derivative with respect to γ for v < λm is negative for α ∗ > (2v − λ) γ∗ − v or
λ + 2λ > 3v and positive otherwise. Then, γ∗ jumps from 0 to 1 as α∗ becomes sufficiently
small. For γ∗ = 1, α∗ = (λ−v)
2 and the mark-up increases with the difference between high-
valuation potential buyers’ and original owners’ valuation. Again, optimal property rights
must be complete if v ≥ λm. Proposition 2 takes stock of the analysis of this section:
Proposition 2: The optimal property rights level γ∗ decreases with the mark-up α∗,
which in turn is larger the higher the dispersion in the traders’ valuations λ− v is.
Proposition 2 not only rationalizes some of the evidence discussed in sections 2 and 4, but
it also helps make sense of growing evidence on the weakness of property rights on renewable
resources in the presence of market power. Common access to the fishing harvest together
with individual transferable quotas indeed are more often observed in Nova Scotia and New
Zealand where the fishermen’s market power is the strongest (Croutzet and Lasserre, 2017).14
3.2.2 Property Rights and Lemons-type Distortions
As noticed by Hasen and McAdams (1997), “theft may avoid the “lemons” problem.”
Following Guerriero (2016a), I maintain here that λ = 0 and that the original owners have
private information on v, which is drawn from an uniform distribution with support [ λ, λ ]
and correlated with the valuation of the potential buyers. In particular, ∆/2 < 1 of them
value x at θv, 1−∆ of them have valuation αv, and the remainder gain from consuming x
a payoff v/θ with θ > 2 > α > 1. Here, θ gages the polarization of the potential buyers’
preferences, α covers the role that exogenous transaction costs have in the basic setup and
represents a measure of the difference between the payoff of middle-valuation potential buyers
and the average payoff of the original owners, and a rise in ∆ constitutes a mean-preserving
spread of the distribution of the potential buyers’ valuation. These three parameters em-
phasize the impact of lemon-type distortions on allocative efficiency. To illustrate, middle
and low-valuation potential buyers expropriate (do not consume) if γ∗ < (=) 1 since the ex-
pected value of x is pL/2 because at pL an original owner sells only if v ≤ pL. High-valuation
potential buyers buy (expropriate) if γ∗ ≥ (<) 2 θ , and society maximizes the linear function
14Focusing on the fishing industry, Croutzet and Lasserre (2017) also show that the strength of the property rights on renewable resources should fall with the elasticity of output to effort and rise with the price elasticity of demand, the number of firms, and the difference between input and output values.
13
θλm ∆
2 + (1−∆) [(1− γ)αλm + γλm] +
[ (1− γ) λm
θ + γλm
] ∆
2 (4)
for γ∗ ≥ 2 θ
and (1− γ) [ (1−∆)α + θ2+1
θ ∆ 2
] λm + γλm otherwise. As a consequence, the
derivative of society’s problem with respect to γ is now positive for γ∗ ≥ 2 θ
and ∆→ 1 and
negative otherwise. Intuitively, as the share of middle-valuation potential buyers for which
x will be misallocated under complete property rights becomes less important because of a
rise in heterogeneity, optimal property rights get complete. Similarly, a sufficiently large rise
in transaction costs—as driven by an α big enough—induces a decrease in γ∗ from 1 to 0 for
∆→ 0. Proposition 3 recaps the main findings of this section analysis:
Proposition 3: Optimal property rights γ∗ fall with the lemon-type distortions α, which
in turn constitute a measure of the dispersion in the traders’ valuations.
Proposition 2 not only clears up some of the evidence illustrated in sections 2 and 4, but
it also helps explain recent stylized facts about sharing economies. In particular, Lee (2016)
builds on 2008 data on BitTorrent private-network file sharing activity and album sales to
conclude that the former has no impact (a positive effect) on top(mid)-tier artists’ sales for
which asymmetric information on perceived talent is the least (most) detrimental.
3.2.3 Property Rights and Incomplete Contracting Costs
Setup.—Consider now a mass one of upstream firms and a mass one of downstream firms.
The latter can employ two technologies to produce x. The “old” one does not necessitate
any input from the upstream firm, and it produces one unit of output of value δλ with δ < 1,
λ uniformly distributed over [ λ, λ ] , l ≡ λ− λ, λ > v > λ, and λm ≡
( λ+ λ
) /2. The “new”
technology instead delivers one unit of output of value λ and requires a preliminary phase,
whose cost v is borne by the downstream firm, and then the provision by the upstream firm
of an input whose cost c is 0 with probability 0 < α < 1 and (1− δ)λ otherwise.15 While
both costs and the firms’ payoffs are observable, unverifiable, and ex ante non contractible,
only the cost of the input is ex post contractible. Without loss of generality in particular, I
15Should the low cost be µ < (1− δ)λ, the social welfare will equal α ∫ λ λ̂ λ−v l dλ+(1− α)
∫ λ λ̂ λ−v−µ
l dλ+ ∫ λ̂ λ δλ l dλ
with λ̂ ≡ v+γα1−δ ≥ λ̃ and the whole argument of this section will go through unchanged.
14
maintain that after the preliminary phase the upstream firm has all the bargaining power.16
As a result, the cost uncertainty creates with odds α an “appropriable quasi-rent” (1− δ)λ,
which is larger the more productive the new technology is relative to the old one, and in turn
the incentive for the upstream firm to always claim that the cost realization is high (Barzel,
1989). Only with probability γ however, the upstream firm is legally allowed to charge the
high cost. Hence, γ captures the strength of the upstream firm’s property rights on his
input relative to the power of the downstream firms’ rights on x. When the input is an idea
or know-how for instance, v might be seen as the expenses supported by the downstream
firm to let the upstream firm understand how to incorporate his input in the old production
process, c is the cost of providing the input, and γ can be interpreted as the probability
that, in a lawsuit for breach of contract launched by the downstream firm, a court allows the
upstream firm to charge for the input provision (1− δ)λ instead of 0. This setup squares
with the idea that courts display personal biases and arbitrarily choose what to find when
certain states are hard to verify and so subject to interpretation (Gennaioli, 2013). Then,
the parameter γ can also be seen as the share of pro-upstream firms courts.
The timing of the institutional and economic activities is the following. At time t0, γ is
chosen to maximize the social welfare, which is the sum of the upstream and downstream
firms’ payoffs. At time t1, each downstream firm selects her preferred technology. If the old
one is employed, production is immediate, otherwise each downstream firm is matched to an
upstream one and, within each match, the two firms sign a contract establishing that in time
t2 the upstream firm has residual rights on his input and all bargaining power at renegotiation
(Grossman and Hart, 1986). At time t2, first the preliminary phase is concluded, then the
input cost is realized and the downstream firm makes a take-it-or-leave-it request to the
downstream firm. Next, the latter can either accept, reject and turn to the old technology,
or reject and exploit the available legal remedies. In this last case, the downstream and
upstream firms’ payoffs are determined by the prevailing protection of property rights γ.
Interpretation.—The parameter α should be seen as a general measure of incomplete
contracting costs. To elaborate, the conflict between upstream and downstream firms re-
16Under the usual assumption of Nash bargaining indeed, the upstream firm will require for c = 0 an input price equal to (1− δ) λ2 . Then, the new technology will be adopted for all λ larger than
2v α(1−δ) , which is
inefficiently higher than λ̃, and the gist of the whole analysis will continue to hold true.
15
sembles again that between a creditor/minority shareholder and a majority stockholder who
can tunnel value out of the firm through a complaisant management asserting that investing
in a new activity needs resources that are ex ante non contractible. Similarly, the contrast
between the two firms is strategically equal to the interaction between a principal and an
agent who can breach their contract by claiming that the ex ante non contractible cost of
using a new technology is (1− δ)λ instead of being 0 (Ganglmair, 2017).
Equilibrium.—For γ∗ = 1, the downstream firm obtains δλ− v with the new technology
and δλ with the old one. Hence, she prefers the latter and the social welfare equals ∫ λ λ δλ l dλ,
which is inefficiently lower than the ex ante efficient equilibrium prescribing technological
innovation and a downstream’s (upstream’s) expected payoff of λ− λ̃ (0) for λ ≥ λ̃ ≡ v α(1−δ) .
Incomplete property rights can solve this hold-up failure since they allow the down-
stream firm to obtain from adopting the new technology λ − v with probability 1 − γ and
δλ − v otherwise and the upstream firm to get from the input provision the expected loss
(1− α) (1− δ)λ with probability 1− γ and the expected gain α (1− δ)λ otherwise. Hence,
the downstream firm will prefer the new technology for λ ≥ λ̂ ≡ v (1−δ)(1−γ) , and the upstream
firm will produce only if property rights are sufficiently strong or γ ∗
(1−γ∗) ≥ 1−α α ↔ γ∗ ≥ 1−α.
For γ∗ ≥ 1−α and λ̂ < λ↔ v < α (1− δ)λ, society maximizes the strictly concave function
α
∫ λ λ̂
λ− v l
dλ+ (1− α) ∫ λ λ̂
δλ− v l
dλ+
∫ λ̂ λ
δλ
l dλ, (5)
which decreases with γ for−dλ̂ dγ
[ αλ̂+ (1− α) δλ̂− v − δλ̂
] = − v
2(α−1+γ) (1−δ)(1−γ)3 ≤ 0 or if γ ≥ 1−α.
To elaborate, a rise in γ ≥ 1− α has the welfare decreasing marginal effect of shrinking the
set of matches for which the downstream firm adopts the new technology. Yet, a γ∗ weakly
larger than 1 − α is necessary to push the upstream firm to participate in the production
process. Therefore, γ∗ = 1− α. The larger the odds α of a positive appropriable quasi-rent
are and thus the more severe asset specificities are, the lower γ∗ should be to convince the
downstream firm to adopt the new technology and the upstream firm to provide his input.17
Crucially, the upstream firm is indifferent between charging as input price the expected
17This incentive will be unnecessary, should the cost be certain. In this case, full property rights will contem- poraneously solve the hold-up failure and assure the upstream firm’s participation constraint.
16
cost and holding-up the downstream firm given the legal remedies at his disposal γ∗. By
assuming that if indifferent he selects the former strategy, then the setup produces no hold-
up in equilibrium. For α sufficiently large moreover, the welfare with incomplete property
rights and technological innovation is larger than that without innovation. The latter also
describes the λ̂ ≥ λ scenario. Proposition 4 sums up the main conclusions of this section:
Proposition 4: Optimal property rights γ∗ fall with the incomplete contracting costs α,
which in turn are a measure of the likelihood that the new technology is more productive.
Recognizing that both parties should be incentivized to foster technological diffusion,
proposition 4 entails that, differently from Grossman and Hart (1986), Hart and Moore
(1990), and Williamson (2010), asset allocation is optimized by alternatively leaving residual
claimant each party. This result has key ramifications for the theory of the firm.18
More generally, the findings of this section are not only coherent with some of the es-
timates discussed in sections 2 and 4, but they also help make sense of anecdotal evidence
on the positive link between the strength of the downstream firm’s intellectual property
rights—a high 1 − γ∗—and the severity of asset specificities. In particular, Burk and Mc-
Donnel (2007) document that stronger and easier to obtain downstream firm’s intellectual
property rights—i.e., trade secrecy and copyright instead of patents—are typically granted
whenever asset specificities are particularly severe, i.e., technological businesses, such as the
software industry, and the entertainment industries.19 Furthermore, these remedies allow the
downstream firm to impose on her employees and upstream partners non-disclosure agree-
ments, work-for-hire provisions, and non-compete clauses reducing their ability to exploit
proprietary information, i.e., a low γ∗ (Burk and McDonnel, 2007). “From the standpoint of
employee incentive [indeed], trade secrecy [and copyright are the] most expensive method of
protection [since they include] forms of intellectual capital most likely to become commingled
[. . . ] from the skills or knowledge of an employee” [Burk and McDonnel 2007, p. 609].
18When the two firms can integrate, they will do so only for matches such that λ ≥ v(1−δ)α = v
(1−δ)(1−γ∗) .
Therefore, any cost of integration discourages firm formation and leaves unchanged the analysis, which can also be interpreted as describing an employer-employee interaction within already formed firms.
19First, trade secrecy and copyright arise spontaneously, upon fixation of a creative work in a tangible medium of expression, whereas patent are granted only upon the disclosure of the claimed invention (Burk and McDonnel, 2007). Second, they receive a longer protection, i.e., respectively perpetual monopoly and the author’s life plus 50 to 100 years rather than the 20 years of patent protection (Burk and McDonnel, 2007).
17
3.3 Robustness Checks
In this section, I document the robustness of the main model implications to two key
alternative assumptions, i.e., the possibility that part of the population is excluded from
institutional design and the possibility for the original owners to decide whether to produce
the good or invest on it before trading (see the Internet appendix for the relative proofs).
3.3.1 The Political Economy of Property Rights Protection
Thus far, I have examined the design of property rights on exchangeable value under a
perfect veil of ignorance, behind which everybody is identical, and the choice of property
rights on innovation activities by downstream and upstream firms with equal political power.
Reality however is often different. To evaluate this positive side of property rights protection,
I consider a situation in which the minority who selects γ either knows his future role in the
economy (as in Alesina, Aghion, and Trebbi, [2004]) or is endowed with important inputs
and thus can exclude the rest of the population from the social welfare maximization.
It seems natural to think that, in the case of exogenously determined transaction costs,
the “insiders” are the original owners and the potential buyers with the highest valuation—
i.e., whose λ ∈ [ λ+ �, λ
] . In this scenario, γ∗ maximizes
∫ λ λ̂ λ−α l dλ +
∫ λ̂ λ+�
(1−γ)λ+γv l
dλ + γv� l
for λ̂ < λ and W FE − (1− γ) � 2+2�λ
2l otherwise. Comparing both expressions with equation
(1) suggests that γ∗ still falls with α for � not too large, but it is set inefficiently high by
individuals who do not face type uncertainty (see the appendix), e.g., Zamindari system of
taxation allowing Indian landowners to expropriate evading tenants who were often more
productive (Besley and Ghatak, 2010). If instead the excluded potential buyers have valu-
ation higher than λ − �, γ∗ decreases with α for � small and equals (is higher than) the γ∗
found in the basic setup if interior (otherwise) as illustrated in the appendix.
When instead the transaction costs are endogenously driven by market power, α∗ contin-
ues to be determined as in section 3.2.1 and thus a rise in γ still has only an infra-marginal
effect on society’s objective function. As a result, equation (3) implies that the analysis is
unchanged when high-valuation potential buyers are excluded from the institutional design
and that γ∗ is set too high and falls with α∗ for � small when instead low-valuation potential
buyers are kept out. Similarly, in the scenario of transaction costs endogenously determined
18
by lemon-type distortions, a gaze at equation (4) suggests that equilibrium property rights
are again inefficiently high and decrease with α provided that � is not too large. Finally, a
glance at equation (5) clarifies that excluding a sufficiently small group of either high- or
low-λ downstream firms from the institutional design does not affect at all the equilibrium
when the transaction costs are endogenously driven by incomplete contracting.
3.3.2 The Disincentive to Effort Effect of Weak Property Rights
Production.—As highlighted in section 1, all the other contributions documenting that
weak property rights can be optimal focus on endowment economies. Here, I prove that the
mechanisms illustrated in sections 3.1, 3.2.1, and 3.2.2 survive when production is introduced
in my theoretical framework. This time, original owners decide between t1 and t2 whether
to produce x at the cost κ < v. Therefore, there is no production for γ∗ = 0 and λ̂ ≥ λ, but
there can be when the original owners’ expected utility is weakly positive for γ∗ > 0 and so
λ̂ < λ. To elaborate, the original owners’ expected utility increases with γ∗, and therefore
there is a γ̃ such that x is produced only if γ∗ ≥ γ̃. Since production creates value also for
the potential buyers, society always selects the maximum γ̂ between γ̃ and γ∗ for κ not too
large. In the most interesting case of endogenous transaction costs finally, γ̃ weakly decreases
with α for λ sufficiently large and v not too small compared to α. This last comparative
statics leaves qualitatively unaffected the main model testable implication.
Investment.—The standard “security” argument in favor of strong property rights claims
that expropriation induces a disincentive to produce and invest (Besley and Ghatak, 2010).
To understand how this intuition affects the model message, I analyze an investment decision
taken by the original owners between t1 and t2 and raising both the original owners’ and
potential buyers’ valuations to respectively v (1 + ρ) and λ (1 + ρ) with ρ > 0 at the fixed
cost ζ < v.20 This setup is similar to the instance of a production economy.
When the transaction costs are exogenous, original owners invest only if γ∗I > 0 and their
expected utility v (1 + ρ) λ−λ̂I l
+ γ∗I v (1 + ρ) λ̂I−λ l − ζ is weakly positive. Both γ∗I and λ̂I are
as in section 3.1.1 with α/ (1 + ρ) in place of α, and thus γ∗I > γ ∗ and λ̂I < λ̂. Hence,
investment inducement weakly strengthens property rights protection. Since the original
20Continuous investment choices produce an algebra so tangled to be uninformative about the model robustness except in the λ large and v small case when the basic analysis stands intact being dρdγ∗ small.
19
owners’ expected utility rises with γ∗I , there is a γ̃I such that investment goes through only if
optimal property rights are larger than γ̃I . For γ ∗ I > γ̃I , society picks γ
∗ I instead of γ
∗ if the
social welfare is larger at γ∗I with investment than it is at γ ∗ without. For γ∗I ≤ γ̃I instead, γ̃I
is preferred to γ∗ if the social welfare is larger at γ̃I with investment than it is at γ ∗ without.
To elaborate, investment always goes through for α sufficiently small compared to v and ρ
(ζ) not too small (large). For v ≥ λm, then γ∗ = 1 and investment always materializes.
In the case of transaction costs determined by the existence of market power, the fact
that the original owners’ utility is multiplied by 1 + ρ implies that α∗I = α ∗ (1 + ρ) and so
γ∗I = γ ∗ and λ̂I = λ̂. Since this payoff rises with γ
∗ I , investment realizes only if optimal
property rights are larger than γ̃I . As in the production case, γ̃I falls with α when the
mark-up is sufficiently small compared to v. Under the same condition and ρ (ζ) not too
small (large), society picks the maximum γ̂I between γ ∗ I and γI since investment is socially
beneficial. Finally, γ∗I = 1 and thus investment is always successful for v ≥ λm.
For what concerns the scenario of transaction costs driven by lemon-type distortions, a
glance at equation (4) suggests that society’s objective function is now multiplied by 1 + ρ
and the analysis of the basic setup is unchanged for α < 2 1+ρ
, except for the fact that high-
valuation potential buyers buy for γ∗ ≥ 2 θ(1+ρ)
and expropriate otherwise. Once again, the
original owners’ expected utility rises with γ∗I , and so investment prevails only if optimal
property rights are larger than γ̃I . Society then selects γ̂I if investment is welfare enhancing
and, in particular, if its fixed cost is sufficiently small and its return is sufficiently large.
4 Evidence
The main model implication is that incomplete property rights are efficient when transac-
tion costs impede both trade and innovation whether or nor constitution writers are benev-
olent and the disincentive to effort effect of weak property rights is taken into account. As
a consequence, the main model testable prediction can be stated as follows:
Prediction: The strength of property rights decreases with the severity of market friction
and failures (incomplete contracting costs due to asset specificities), which in turn increase
with the dispersion in the traders’ valuation (productivity of the available technologies).
The negative links between the measures of the protection of personal, intellectual, and
20
financial property and the proxies for market frictions and failures documented in section 2
are consistent with such a prediction. Nevertheless, they may be capturing reverse causality,
they may be driven by the confounding effect of relevant omitted variables, or they may be
attenuated by the error in the measurement of transaction costs.
4.1 Identifying Causal Relationships
I pursue several strategies to evaluate whether the correlations documented in section 2
are causal. First, I control for the other main drivers of property rights discussed by the
extant literature. Second, I use selection on observables to assess the likelihood that the
estimates are driven by unobservables. Finally, I devise a 2SLS approach based on the afore-
mentioned positive dependence of market friction and failures (incomplete contracting costs)
on the dispersion in the traders’ valuation (productivity of the available technologies).21
4.1.1 Controlling for Observables
The key variables potentially omitted from the analysis of section 2 are those shaping
property rights through channels other than the trade-off between inefficient exclusion from
trade/innovation and expropriation and associated with transaction costs. They are the de-
velopment level, the inclusiveness of political institutions, the level of state capacity, internal
conflicts, and the extent of human capital accumulation. Next, I illustrate them in turn.
First, transaction costs could affect property rights through their adverse impact on
economic development, which in turn is related to the protection of private rights through
the modernization effect (Williamson, 2010). Accordingly, I consider the natural logarithm
of the output-side real GDP at chained PPPs in 2011 US dollar per capita—Income.
Second, less inclusive political institutions obstruct the distribution of the rents from
innovation and trade among non-elite (North, Wallis, and Weingast, 2009), while easing
the expropriation of the property of private citizens by both politicians and elite members
(Acemoglu and Johnson, 2005). To assess the importance of such a mechanism, I consider
the constraints on the executive authority score from the POLITY IV dataset—Democracy.22
21For the data aggregated at the cross-sectional level moreover, I can confirm the core of the analysis and I cannot reject that transaction costs are exogenous and that the overidentifying restrictions hold.
22To illustrate, the score ranges between one and seven and assumes higher values when the holder of the executive power is accountable to the citizens and/or the government is constrained by checks and balances.
21
Third, low levels of non-produced output worsening the disincentive to effort effect, the
historical incidence of external wars, and German and Scandinavian legal origins are stable
predictors of a state capacity to exchange/innovate and protect private rights (see Besley
and Persson, [2009]; but also Guerriero, [2016b]). While I take into account the last factor
through the fixed country effects, to assess the role of the first two I control for the crude
oil proved reserves in barrels per capita—Reserves—and the share of previous half-century
in which the country was involved in external military conflicts—Conflict-External.
Fourth, inter-groups conflicts are related to both larger transaction costs (Seitz, Tarasov,
and Zakharenko, 2015) and less secure private rights (Ashraf and Galor, 2013). I consider the
role of these connections by incorporating into the analysis the share of previous half-century
in which the country was involved in internal military conflicts—Conflict-Internal.
Fifth, governance provides incentives for investments in human capital (Foss, 2011), which
in turn helps shift labor from traditional to modern sectors and so curb inequality and favor
institutions that protect private property (Cervellati, Fortunato, and Sunde, 2008). To
contemplate the role of human capital, I control for the ratio of total tertiary enrollment
regardless of age to the population of the relative age group—Human-Capital.
Finally, a culture of morality and the efficiency of public enforcement alter the incentives
of intermediaries and thus the balance between protecting property and enhancing the re-
liance on contracts (Dari-Mattiacci and Guerriero, 2015),23 Moreover, they may shape the
intensity of both exchange and innovation (Seitz, Tarasov, and Zakharenko, 2015). Esti-
mates reported in the Internet appendix reveal that considering these factors greatly lowers
the number of available observations but leaves essentially intact the gist of the analysis.
Crucially, including these controls in the specification also factors in the diversity in
preference/productivity, which lowers the contribution to the social welfare of the utilities of
those middle-valuation (productivity) potential buyers (downstream firms) whose exclusion
from trade (innovation) is more socially costly (Guerriero, 2016a). Since transaction costs
might be correlated with heterogeneity, this aspect of the identification strategy is key.
23While I proxy a culture of morality with the first principal component extracted from the level of generalized trust and the importance of respect self-reported to either the World Value Survey or the European Value Study, I measure the efficiency of public enforcement with the first principal component extracted from the number of police personnel and that of professional judges per 100,000 inhabitants as collected from the United Nations’ surveys of crime trends and the operations of criminal justice systems.
22
Panels (A) to (C) of table 4 report the estimates relative to the specifications with
dependent variables Property-Rights, Intellectual-Property, and Shareholders-Protection re-
spectively and considering all together the extra controls. The key observation is that the
coefficients on these regressors are generally jointly insignificant, whereas those on the prox-
ies for transaction costs are negative and significant at 5 percent or better and display a
magnitude almost equal to their counterparts in table 3. In the same spirit, results available
upon request reveal that the impacts of the proxies for transaction costs remain similar when
considered together and that the extra controls contribute only marginally to the total R2.24
4.1.2 Using Selection on Observables to Assess the Bias from Unobservables
Despite my attempts to control for relevant observable factors, OLS estimates may still
be biased by unobservables. To evaluate this issue, I calculate the index proposed by Altonji,
Elder, and Taber (2005) to measure how much stronger selection on unobservables, relative
to selection on observables, must be to explain away the full estimated effect.25 To see how
the index is calculated, consider a regression with a restricted set of control variables and one
with a full set of controls. Next, denote the estimate of the coefficient attached to a proxy for
transaction costs from the first regression βR, where R stands for “restricted,” and that from
the second regression βF , where F stands for “full.” Then, the index is the absolute value
of βF/(βR − βF ). The intuition behind the formula is as follows. The lower the absolute
value of (βR − βF ) is, the less the estimate of the relevant coefficient is affected by selection
on observables, and the stronger selection on unobservables needs to be to explain away the
entire effect. Moreover, the higher the absolute value of βF is, the greater is the effect that
needs to be explained away by selection on unobservables, and thus the higher is the index.
In table 5, I consider the specifications conditioning only for fixed country and year
effects and reported in table 3 as the restricted regressions and those controlling for all
observables in table 4 as the full regressions. The ratios calculated when the dependent
variable is Property-Rights, Intellectual-Property, and Shareholders-Protection are reported
respectively in columns (1) to (3). None of them is less than one, and the median and average
24According to the Shapley value decomposition, their contribution amounts on average only to the 13 percent, whereas the share explained by transaction costs (fixed country and time effects) is the 35 (52) percent.
25I use the version developed by Bellows and Miguel (2009) for possibly endogenous continuous variables.
23
ratios are 60 and 29.2. Therefore, to attribute the entire OLS estimates of the coefficients on
the proxies for transaction costs to selection effects, selection on unobservables would have
to be on average sixty times greater than selection on all observables, which seems unlikely.
4.1.3 2SLS Estimates: Property Rights and Endogenous Transaction Costs
My final strategy is to use instrumental variables. This requires instruments that are
correlated with transaction costs but uncorrelated with any other dimension affecting prop-
erty rights. To achieve this goal, I build on the positive dependence of market friction
and failures (incomplete contracting costs) on the dispersion in the traders’ valuation (pro-
ductivity of the available technologies), and I use as excluded instruments for transaction
costs two one-to-seven indexes. The first one captures the availability for firms of the latest
technologies—Technology-Availability—and the other measures the quality of math and sci-
ence education—Math-Science. This strategy is consistent with Añón Higón et al. (2017),
who build on over one million firm-level data for 23 EU states between 2003 and 2014 to doc-
ument that more labor skilled firms are closer to the productivity frontier and this pattern
is more accentuated in service sectors. As a result, one would expect that the likelihood of
sizable differences in the productivity of firms and, in turn, of sizable dispersion in the payoffs
of their users is smaller in countries endowed with a human capital more apt to absorb ideas
and knowledge. Crucially, it is very difficult to envision that a society’s inclination to spread
and adopt more effectively innovation is systematically related to the protection of property
rights conditional on the inclusiveness of political institutions, the level of state capacity,
internal conflicts, and especially the level of both economic development and human capital
and both time-invariant and country-invariant unobservable factors.
Table 6 reports in panels (A) to (C) the 2SLS estimates of the specifications with
dependent variables respectively Property-Rights, Intellectual-Property, and Shareholders-
Protection and controlling for all observables. Starting from the first stages, both Technology-
Availability and Math-Science have always a negative and generally statistically significant
coefficient. Accordingly, I can always reject that the estimated equation is underidentified
at 1 percent. Turning to the second stages, the proxies for transaction costs have always
negative and strongly significant—at 1 percent—effects on the measures of property rights
24
protection and the attached coefficients display a magnitude remarkably similar to those in
table 4. This evidence entails that the potential endogeneity between transaction costs and
property rights needs not be a source of concerns here. Consistent with this view, I cannot
reject that the overidentifying restrictions hold at a level nowhere lower than 5 percent and I
document in the Internet appendix that the excluded instruments have no direct impact on
property rights in the semi-reduced form regressions. Overall, these patterns provide support
for the inferences made above and confirm the validity of the central model prediction.
5 Conclusions
Here I developed and tested a model clarifying how the protection of property rights
is optimally weakened in the face of sizable costs of trading/innovating, and in particular
market frictions and failures, and how these are more severe whenever the dispersion in the
traders’ valuations and in the productivity of the available technologies are larger.
To characterize the general trade-off between inefficient exclusion from trade/innovation
and expropriation guiding property rights selection, I study both the possibly consensual ex-
change of economic value between its original owner and a potential buyer and a downstream
firm’s choice of whether to produce in-house through an old technology or to adopt a new
one necessitating an upstream firm’s input. In the former case, fully protecting the original
owners’ property implies that some high-valuation potential buyers inefficiently refuse to buy
it because of transaction costs. When instead property rights are weak, low-valuation po-
tential buyers inefficiently expropriate the original owners’ property. The trade-off between
these two misallocations entails that the strength of property rights, and thus the size of
the market, will be more limited the larger transaction costs are regardless of whether they
are driven by frictions outside the control of traders/innovators or determined by the mix of
the dispersion in traders’ valuations and either the original owners’ market power or their
privileged information. A similar conclusion holds true for the upstream firm’s property
rights on his input. Being the relative cost random and ex ante non contractible, a strong
protection of the upstream firms’ property discourages the downstream firms from innovat-
ing because of the risk of being held-up. When instead the upstream firms are only weakly
protected, low-productivity downstream firms inefficiently exploit the input. Balancing these
25
two misallocations entails that the protection of the upstream firms’ property rights (size
of the market) will be weaker (larger) the greater incomplete contracting costs are, i.e., the
higher is the probability of low-cost realization. Crucially, these implications survive when
a minority of traders/innovators has a larger political influence on institutional design and
when the disincentive to effort effect of weak property rights is taken into account.
To evaluate the central model prediction, I focus on a panel of 135 countries spanning
the 2006-2015 period. OLS estimates suggest that the protection of the original owners’
(downstream firms’) property rights is the strongest (weakest) where market frictions—i.e.,
excessive regulation and financial inefficiencies—and failures—i.e., lack of the competitive-
ness of corporate activity and lemons-type distortions (incomplete contracting costs due to
asset specificities)—are the largest. To determine if these relationships are indeed causal,
I pursue several strategies. First, I control not only for fixed country and year effects, but
also for the development level, the inclusiveness of political institutions, the strength of state
capacity, internal conflicts, and the level of human capital. Considering these observables
together leaves the results almost intact. Second, I calculate that selection on unobservables
would have to be on average almost sixty times greater than that of all observables. Finally,
I use as excluded instruments proxies for both the availability of the latest technology and
the quality of math and science education. Conditional on all observables, the 2SLS esti-
mates are strongly consistent with the OLS ones. In addition, the validity of the exclusion
restriction is vindicated by the canonical under-identification and over-identification tests.
I close by highlighting how two central results of my analysis open key avenues for future
research. First, the tendency of property rights toward optimality does not imply that the
existing legal variation is irrelevant and thus does not warrant reforms. On the contrary,
the model reveals that special interests can distort the design of property rights away from
optimality when the political process is less than perfect. Second, weak property rights are
society’s response to the existence of sizable transaction costs, which in turn are driven by
the dispersion in the traders’ valuations and in the productivity of the available technologies,
and therefore their negative correlation with economic outcomes might be—at least partly—
spurious. As a consequence, further research on the relationships among endogenous property
rights, endogenous transaction costs, and economic outcomes is needed.
26
Appendix
Property Rights and Market Power
The first-order condition of society’s problem is − λ̂−λ 2l
( λ̂+ λ− 2v
) = 0, whose left-hand
side is the infra-marginal effect of a rise in γ and might be negative only for v < λm. �
Property Rights and Lemons-type Distortions
The high-valuation potential buyers’ expected payoff from buying θ pL 2 − pL is weakly
greater than her expected payoff from expropriation (1− γ) θ pL 2
for γ∗ higher than 2 θ <
1 being θ > 2. The middle(low)-valuation potential buyers instead do not buy because
αpL 2 −pL(pL2θ −pL) < 0. For γ
∗ ≤ 2 θ , the derivative of society’s objective function with respect
to γ is − [ (1−∆) (α− 1) + (θ−1)
2
θ ∆ 2
] λm, which is negative. For γ
∗ > 2 θ
instead, it equals
− [ (1−∆) (α− 1)− θ−1
θ ∆ 2
] λm, which rises with ∆, is negative for ∆ → 0, and positive for
∆→ 1, and thus γ∗ possibly jumps from 0 to 1 for α (∆) sufficiently small (large). �
Considering a Generic Probability Density Function of the Potential Buyers’ Valuation
In the case of exogenous transaction costs, potential buyers value x at λ ∈ [ λ, λ ]
dis-
tributed according to the log-concave probability density function f with cumulative distri-
bution function F . Then, γ∗ maximizes ∫ λ λ̂
(λ− α) dF (λ) + ∫ λ̂ λ
[(1− γ)λ+ γv] dF (λ) for
λ̂ < λ and W FE otherwise. For λ̂ < λ, γ∗ > 0 is defined by 1−γ ∗
γ∗ vλ̂f
( λ̂ ) − ( λ̂− v
) F ( λ̂ )
+∫ λ̂ λ F (λ) dλ = 0 and society’s objective function is sub-modular in γ and α when
f ′(λ̂) f(λ̂)
<
α v(v+α)
γ∗
1−γ∗ . While the right-hand side of this inequality is greater than α
v(λ−v−α) , its left-hand
side is lower than f ′
f (v + α) since log-concavity of f implies a decreasing f
′
f (Dharmadhikari
and Kumar, 1988). Hence, the inequality is true and thus dγ ∗
dα ≤ 0 for f ′
f (v + α) < α
v(λ−v−α)
or equally if v is sufficiently large (see section 3.1 for the corresponding restriction in the
basic setup). To understand this last remark, notice that the right-hand side of the sufficient
condition increases with v for 2v > λ−α, whereas its left-hand side is negative for v+α larger
than the mode of λ, being every log-concave density function defined on a real support uni-
modal (Dharmadhikari and Kumar, 1988). For λ̂ < λ, the infra-marginal effect of a rise in γ
is [ v − E
( λ|λ ≤ λ̂
)] F ( λ̂ )
, which can be negative only if v < λm = E (λ) ≥ E ( λ|λ ≤ λ̂
) .
For λ̂ < λ and v ≥ λm therefore, γ∗ = 1. For λ̂ < λ and v < λm instead, γ∗ can jump from
0 to the interior solution whenever ∫ λ λ̂
(λ− α) dF (λ) + ∫ λ̂ λ
[(1− γ∗)λ+ γ∗v] dF (λ) > λm.
27
This last condition is more difficult to satisfy the larger the transaction costs are since the
derivative of its left-hand side with respect to α equals −1−γ∗ γ∗
vf ( λ̂ ) − F
( λ )
+ F ( λ̂ ) < 0.
Next, I show that the results produced by the other setups survive to considering any f .
When the original owners have market power, two observations are key. First, the mark-
up α∗ maximizes now the original owners’ expected payoff ∫ λ λ̂
(v + α) dF (λ) + ∫ λ̂ λ γ∗vdF (λ),
whose derivative with respect to α is 1 − F ( λ̂ ) − ( λ̂− v
) f ( λ̂ )
. Hence, dα ∗
dγ = λ̂ and
thus dλ̂ dγ
= ( dα∗
dγ γ − v − α∗
) 1 γ2
= 0. Again, the effect of a rise in the strength of optimal
property rights on society’s objective function ∫ λ λ̂ λdF (λ)+
∫ λ̂ λ
[(1− γ)λ+ γv] dF (λ) equals
− λ̂−λ 2
( λ̂+ λ− 2v
) f ( λ̂ )
, which is negative for v+α ∗
γ∗ + λ − 2v > 0 and positive otherwise.
As in the baseline case of a uniform distribution f , γ∗ jumps from 0 to 1 as α∗, which is
either 0 or its maximum value α = min { v, λ− v
} , becomes sufficiently small.
Turning to the scenario of transaction costs driven by lemon-type distortions, it follows
from society’s objective function that only the mean of the potential buyers’ valuation dis-
tribution λm matters. This remark highlights the full generality of the analysis.
For what finally concerns the case of transaction costs endogenously determined by in-
complete contracting, society maximizes α ∫ λ λ̂
(λ− v) dF (λ) + (1− α) ∫ λ λ̂
(δλ− v) dF (λ) +∫ λ̂ λ δλdF (λ), which strictly increases with γ when −dλ̂
dγ
[ αλ̂+ (1− α) δλ̂− v − δλ̂
] f ( λ̂ )
=
− v 2(α−1+γ)
(1−δ)(1−γ)3f ( λ̂ ) > 0 or if γ < 1 − α and weakly decreases otherwise. Hence, the unique
and global solution is γ∗ = 1− α as in the baseline scenario of a uniform distribution f .
Crucially, this section analysis applies straightforwardly to the political economy case. �
The Political Economy of Property Rights Protection
In the case of exogenous transaction costs and excluded low-valuation potential buyers,
the derivative of the objective function is v 2−α2 (γ∗)2
+ (λ+ �)2− 2vλ = 0 for λ̂ < λ and v−λm + 2�λ+�2
2l otherwise, the infra-marginal effect of a rise in γ for λ̂ < λ is −(λ̂−λ−�)(λ̂+λ+�−2v)
2l + 2v�
2l ,
and the second-order conditions are as in the basic setup. Thus, γ∗ is set inefficiently high,
falls with α provided that (λ+ �)2−2vλ < 0 or � not too large, and possibly jumps from 0 to
the interior solution for α sufficiently small under the same condition discussed in the basic
setup. When instead to be excluded are high-valuation potential buyers, society maximizes
the objective function ∫ λ−� λ̂
λ−α l dλ+
∫ λ̂ λ
(1−γ)λ+γv l
dλ for λ̂ < λ and W FE − (1− γ) 2�λ−�2 2l
oth-
erwise. Both the infra-marginal effect of a rise in γ and the first and second-order conditions
28
for a positive solution are as in the baseline analysis, whereas for λ̂ ≥ λ the first-order con-
dition is v−λm + 2�λ−� 2
2l and thus leads again to an inefficiently large γ∗. The condition such
that γ∗ possibly jumps from 0 to the positive solution is easier to satisfy the smaller α is for
α < γ∗ ( λ− v − �
) and thus under the basic model restrictions on α for � small.
When original owners have market power, the only relevant case is λ < λ̂ and society max-
imizes ∫ λ λ̂ λ l dλ+
∫ λ̂ λ+�
(1−γ)λ+γv l
dλ, whose derivative with respect to γ is −(λ̂−λ−�)(λ̂+λ+�−2v) 2l
+
2v� 2l
. Hence, equilibrium property rights jump from 0 to 1 for α∗ and � sufficiently small.
Turning to the case of transaction costs driven by lemon-type distortions and low(high)-
valuation potential buyers not participating in the institutional design, society’s objec-
tive function is that of the basic setup with (1− γ) λm θ
( ∆ 2 − � )
in place of (1− γ) λm θ
∆ 2
((1− γ) θλm (
∆ 2 − � )
in place of (1− γ) θλm∆2 for γ ∗ ≤ 2
θ and θλm
( ∆ 2 − � )
in place of
θλm ∆ 2
otherwise). While for γ∗ ≤ 2 θ
the first-order condition of society’s problem equals
− [ (1−∆) (α− 1) + (θ−1)
2
θ ∆ 2 − �
θ
] λm (−
[ (1−∆) (α− 1) + (θ−1)
2
θ ∆ 2 − �θ
] λm) and so it is
negative for � not too large, for γ∗ > 2 θ
it equals − [ (1−∆) (α− 1)− θ−1
θ ∆ 2 − �
θ
] λm and
thus is negative for ∆ and � small and α large (the baseline case analysis applies).
For what finally concerns the case of transaction costs endogenously determined by in-
complete contracting, the equilibrium is the same whether or not a sufficiently small group
of either high- or low-λ downstream firms is kept out of the institutional design. �
Production
In the case of exogenous transaction costs, the original owners’ expected utility equals v(λ−λ̂)
l +
γ∗v(λ̂−λ) l
− κ and thus γ̃ is implicitly defined by v[λ−(v+α)γ̃ −1]
l +
γ̃v[(v+α)γ̃−1−λ] l
= κ,
whose left-hand side rises with γ̃ because −dλ̂ dγ̃
v l
(1− γ̃) + v(λ̂−λ) l
= vλ̂ γ̃l
(1− γ̃) + v(λ̂−λ) l ≥
0. Thus, production realizes for γ∗ ≥ γ̃. When the original owners have market power,
their expected utility is (v+α∗)(λ−λ̂)
l +
γ∗v(λ̂−λ) l
− κ, and γ̃ is defined by (v+α ∗)[λ−(v+α∗)γ̃−1]
l +
γ̃v[(v+α∗)γ̃−1−λ] l
= κ, whose left-hand side rises with γ̃ because −dλ̂ dγ̃
v(1−γ̃)+α∗ l
+ v(λ̂−λ)
l =
λ̂ γ̃l
[v (1− γ̃) + α∗]+ v(λ̂−λ) l ≥ 0 and rises with α if − dλ̂
dα v(1−γ̃)+α∗
l + λ−λ̂
l = −v(1−γ̃)+α
∗
γ̃l + λ−λ̂
l ≥ 0
or for λ large and v not too small compared to α∗ and so γ∗ → 1. Hence, production realizes
for γ∗ ≥ γ̃, and dγ̃ dα ≤ 0. For what finally concerns the scenario of transaction costs driven
by lemon-type distortions, the original owners’ expected utility is ∆ 2 pL +
( 1− ∆
2
) γ∗λm − κ
and γ̃ is independent of α being equal to 2κ−∆pL (2−∆)λm . Once again, x is produced if γ
∗ ≥ γ̃. �
29
Investment
With exogenous transaction costs, potential buyers buy if λ (1 + ρ) − v (1 + ρ) − α ≥
(1− γI)λ or λ ≥ λ̂I ≡ v+α(1+ρ) −1
γI and thus society’s objective function is
∫ λ λ̂I
λ(1+ρ)−α l
dλ +
(1 + ρ) ∫ λ̂I λ
(1−γ)λ+γv l
dλ, γ∗I = v2−( α1+ρ)
2
λ(2v−λ) , and the original owners’ expected payoff from in-
vestment equals v (1 + ρ) (λ−λ̂I)
l + γ∗I v (1 + ρ)
λ̂I−λ l − ζ, whose derivative with respect to γ∗I
is −dλ̂I dγ∗I v (1 + ρ)
(1−γ∗I ) l
+ v (1 + ρ) λ̂I−λ l ≥ 0. For γ∗I > γ̃I , society picks γ∗I if the social
welfare is larger at γ∗I with investment than it is at γ ∗ without or whenever the inequality∫ λ
λ̂I
λ(1+ρ)−α l
dλ− ∫ λ λ̂ λ−α l dλ+ (1 + ρ)
∫ λ̂I λ
(1−γ∗I )λ+γ∗I v l
dλ− ∫ λ̂ λ
(1−γ∗)λ+γ∗v l
dλ− ζ ≥ 0 holds. The
left hand side of this condition is larger than (1 + ρ) ( γ∗λ̂2 − γ∗I λ̂2I
) + (γ∗I − γ∗)λ
2 (1 + ρ) +
2v [ (1 + ρ) γ∗I
( λ̂I − λ
) − γ∗
( λ̂− λ
)] −2α
( λ̂− λ̂I
) − ζl, which is positive for α sufficiently
small compared to v and so γ∗I → γ∗ and ρ (ζ) not too small (large). A similar analysis
applies to the γ∗I ≤ γ̃I scenario when society chooses γ̃I and not γ∗ if the social welfare is
larger at γ̃I with investment than it is at γ ∗ without investment. In the former case, λ̂I is
evaluated at γ̃I . If v ≥ λm finally, then γ∗ = 1 and investment is certain.
When the original owners have market power, their expected utility rises with and falls
with α if − dλ̂ dα
v(1−γ̃I)(1+ρ)+α∗ l
+ λ−λ̂ l
= −v(1−γ̃I)+α ∗
γ̃I(1+ρ)l + λ−λ̂
l ≥ 0 or if v is not too small compared
to α∗ since then γ∗ → 1. Hence, γ̃I falls with α when the mark-up is sufficiently small
compared to v and society selects γ̂I if investment is welfare enhancing. For γ ∗ > γ̃I , this is
the case if ρ ∫ λ λ̂ λ l dλ+ρ
∫ λ̂ λ
(1−γ∗)λ+γ∗v l
dλ− ζ ≥ 0 and therefore for ρ (ζ) not too small (large).
For γ∗ ≤ γ̃I instead, the analysis is as with exogenous transaction costs and γ̃I is selected
for α small compared to v and so γ∗I → γ∗ and ρ (ζ) not too small (large).
For what finally concerns the scenario of transaction costs driven by lemon-type distor-
tions, the original owners’ expected utility is ∆ 2 pL (1 + ρ) +
( 1− ∆
2
) γ∗λm (1 + ρ) − κ, and
γ̃I = 2κ−∆pL(1+ρ) (2−∆)λm(1+ρ) , and it is thus independent of α. As discussed in the text, the choice of
γ∗I is as in the basic setup, investment prevails only if optimal property rights are larger
than γ̃I , and society then selects γ̂I if investment is welfare enhancing. For γ ∗ > γ̃I , this
is the case if θλm ∆ 2
+ (1−∆) [(1− γ∗)αλm + γ∗λm] + [ (1− γ∗) λm
θ + γ∗λm
] ∆ 2 − ζρ−1 ≥ 0
and so for ρ (ζ) not too small (large). For γ∗ ≤ γ̃I instead, society selects γ̃I if ρθλm∆2 +
[(1 + ρ) (1− γ̃I)− (1− γ∗)] [ (1−∆)αλm + λmθ
∆ 2
] + ( 1− ∆
2
) (γ̃I − γ∗)λm− ζ ≥ 0 and so for
α sufficiently small compared to v and thus γ∗I → γ∗ and ρ (ζ) not too small (large). �
30
References
Acemoglu, Daron, and Simon Johnson. 2005. “Unbundling Institutions.” Journal of Politi-
cal Economy, 113: 949-995.
Aghion, Philippe, Yann Algan, Pierre Cahuc, and Andrei Shleifer. 2010. “Regulation and
Distrust.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125: 1015-1049.
Altonji, Joseph G., Todd E. Elder, and Christopher R. Taber. 2005. “Selection on Observed
and Unobserved Variables: Assessing the Effectiveness of Catholic Schools.” Journal of
Political Economy, 113: 151-184.
Añón Higón, M. Dolores, Juan A. Máñez, Maŕıa E. Rochina-Barrachina, Amparo Sanchis,
and Juan A. Sanchis. 2017. “The Determinants of the Distance to TFP Frontier among
European Firms.” Unpublished.
Arruñada, Benito, Giorgio Zanarone, and Nuno Garoupa. 2017. “Property Rights in Se-
quential Exchange.” Unpublished.
Ashraf, Quamrul, and Oded Galor. 2013. “Genetic Diversity and the Origins of Cultural
Fragmentation.” American Economic Review, 103: 528-533.
Bar-Gill, Oren, and Nicola Persico. 2016. “Exchange Efficiency with Weak Ownership
Rights.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 8: 230-267.
Barry, Jordan M., John William Hatfield, and Scott Duke Kominers. 2014. “Coasean Keep-
Away: Voluntary Transaction Costs.” Unpublished.
Barzel, Yoram. 1989. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. Cambridge University Press.
Bellows, John, and Edward Miguel. 2009. “War and Local Collective Action in Sierra
Leone.” Journal of Public Economics, 93: 1144-1157.
Besley, Timothy, and Maitreesh Ghatak. 2010. “Property Rights and Economic Develop-
ment.” In Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. V. Mark Rosenzweig and Dani
Rodrik, eds. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
31
Besley, Timothy, and Torsten Persson. 2009. “The Origins of State Capacity: Property
Rights, Taxation and Politics.” American Economic Review, 99: 1218-1244.
Bond, Eric W., and Kamal Saggi. 2017. “Compulsory Licensing and Patent Protection: a
North-South Perspective.” Forthcoming at the Economic Journal.
Bouckeart, Boudewijn, and Gerrit De Geest. 1995. “Private Takings, Private Taxes and
Private Compulsory Services: The Economic Doctrine of Quasi Contracts.” International
Review of Law and Economics, 15: 463-487.
Brueckner, Jan K., and Harris Selod. 2009. “A Theory of Urban Squatting and Land-Tenure
Formalization in Developing Countries.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy,
1: 28-51.
Burk, Dan L., and Brett McDonnel. 2007. “The Goldilocks Hypothesis: Balancing Intellec-
tual Property Rights at the Boundary of the Firm.” University of Illinois Law Review,
2: 575-636.
Calabresi, Guido, and Melamed, A. Douglas. 1972. “Property Rules, Liability Rules and
Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral.” Harvard Law Review, 85: 1089-1128.
Cervellati, Matteo, Piergiuseppe Fortunato, and Uwe Sunde. 2008. “Hobbes to Rousseau:
Inequality, Institutions, and Development.” Economic Journal, 118: 1354-1384.
Charnoz, Olivier, and Ashwini Swain. 2012. “In Pursuit of Energy Efficiency in India’s
Agriculture: Fighting “Free Power” or Working with it?” Unpublished.
Cook, R. Dennis. 1977. “Detection of Influential Observations in Linear Regression.” Tech-
nometrics, 19: 15-18.
Croutzet, Alexandre, and Pierre Lasserre. 2017. “Optimal Completeness of Property Rights
on Renewable Resources in the Presence of Market Power.” Resource and Energy Eco-
nomics, 49: 16-32.
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe. 2012. “Endogenous Transaction Costs.” Unpublished.
32
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe, and Carmine Guerriero. 2015. “Law and Culture: A Theory of
Comparative Variation in Bona Fide Purchase Rules.” Oxford Journal of Legal Studies,
35: 543-574.
Dharmadhikari, Sudhakar, and Joag-Dev, Kumar. 1988. Unimodality, Convexity, and Ap-
plications. Boston, MA: Academic Press.
Foss Nicolai J. 2011. “Human Capital and Transaction Cost Economics.” In the Oxford
Handbook of Human Capital, Alan BurtonJones and J.C. Spender, eds. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Ganglmair, Bernhard. 2017. “Efficient Material Breach of Contract.” Forthcoming at the
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization.
Gennaioli, Nicola. 2013. “Optimal Contracts with Enforcement Risk.” Journal of the Euro-
pean Economic Association, 11: 59-62.
Ghosh, Shubha. 2014. “The Implementation of Exhaustion Policies: Lessons from National
Experiences.” Unpublished.
Grossman, Sanford J., and Hart, Oliver D. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A
Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy, 94: 691-719.
Guerriero, Carmine. 2016a. “Endogenous Property Rights.” Journal of Law and Economics,
59: 313-358.
Guerriero, Carmine. 2016b. “Endogenous Legal Traditions and Economic Outcomes.” Jour-
nal of Comparative Economics, 44: 416-433
Hart, Oliver, and John Moore. 1990. “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm.” Journal
of Political Economy, 98: 1119-1158.
Hasen, Richard L., and Richard H. McAdams. 1997. “The Surprisingly Complex Case
Against Theft.” International Review of Law and Economics, 17: 367-378.
33
Johnson, Simon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2000.
“Tunneling.” American Economic Review, 90: 22-27.
Jordan, Jim. 2006. “Pillage and Property.” Journal of Economic Theory, 131: 26-44.
North, Douglass C., John J. Wallis, Barry R. Weingast. 2009. Violence and Social Orders:
A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Piazzesi, Monika, Martin Schneider, and Johannes Stroebel. 2017. “Segmented Housing
Search.” Unpublished.
Piccione, Michele, and Ariel Rubinstein. 2007. “Equilibrium in the Jungle.” Economic
Journal, 117: 883-896.
Sackman, Julius, at al. 2013. Nichols on Eminent Domain. Albany, New York, NY: Matthew
Bender.
Segal, Ilya, and Michael Whinston. 2016. “Property Rights and the Efficiency of Bargain-
ing.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 14: 1287-1328.
Seitz, Michael, Alexander Tarasov, Roman Zakharenko. 2015. “Trade Costs, Conflicts, and
Defense Spending.” Journal of International Economics, 95: 305-318.
Smith, Adam. 2017. “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.”
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. 2010. “Transaction Cost Economics: The Natural Progression.”
American Economic Review, 100: 673-690.
World Economic Forum—WEF. 2015. “The Global Competitiveness Report 2014-2015.”
Geneva: WEF Press.
34
Tables and Figures
Table 1: Full Sample Albania; Algeria; Angola; Argentina; Armenia; Australia; Austria; Azerbaijan; Bahrain; Bangladesh; Belgium; Benin; Bhutan; Bolivia; Botswana; Brazil; Bulgaria; Burkina Faso; Burundi; Cambodia; Cameroon; Canada; Chad; Chile; China; Colombia; Costa Rica; Cote d’Ivoire; Croatia; Cyprus; Czech Republic; Denmark; Dominican Republic; Ecuador; Egypt; El Salvador; Estonia; Ethiopia; Finland; France; Gabon; Gambia; Germany; Ghana; Greece; Guatemala; Guinea; Honduras: Hungary; India; Indonesia; Iran; Ireland; Israel; Italy; Jamaica; Japan; Jordan; Kazakhstan; Kenya; Kuwait; Kyrgyz Republic; Lao; Latvia; Lebanon; Lesotho; Liberia; Lithuania; Luxembourg; Macedonia; Mada- gascar; Malawi; Malaysia; Mali; Mauritania; Mauritius; Mexico; Moldova; Mongolia; Montenegro; Morocco; Mozambique; Myanmar; Namibia; Nepal; Netherlands; New Zealand; Nicaragua; Nigeria; Norway; Oman; Pakistan; Panama; Paraguay; Peru; Philippines; Poland; Portugal; Qatar; Romania; Russia; Rwanda; Saudi Arabia; Senegal; Serbia; Sierra Leone; Singapore; Slovak Republic; Slovenia; South Africa; Spain; Sri Lanka; Suriname; Swaziland; Sweden; Switzerland; Syria; Taiwan; Tajikistan; Tanzania; Thailand; Trinidad & Tobago; Tunisia; Turkey; Uganda; Ukraine; United Arab Emirates; United Kingdom; United States; Uruguay; Venezuela; Vietnam; Yemen; Zambia; Zimbabwe.
Table 2: Summary of Variables Variable Definition and Sources Statistics
Property-Rights: Index ranging between one and seven and gaging the strength of generic property 4.388 rights. Source: 2006-2015 EOS, available at https://www.weforum.org/reports/ (1.034)
Property Intellectual-Property:
Index ranging between one and seven and gaging how strong are intellectual 3.713 rights: property rights. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (1.124)
Shareholders-Protection: Index ranging between one and seven and gaging to what extent are the interests 4.305 of minority shareholders protected by the legal system. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.750)
Over-Regulation: Index ranging between one and seven and gaging how burdensome is for firms to 3.708 comply with governmental administrative requirements. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.658)
Unavailability-Financing: Index ranging between one and seven and gaging the financial sector difficulties 2.489 in providing products and services to businesses. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.955)
Market-Dominance: Index ranging between one and seven and falling with the competitiveness of 3.168
Transaction corporate activity. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.837) costs:
Trade-Barriers: Index ranging between one and seven and gaging how much non-tariff barriers curb 2.545 imported goods ability to compete with domestic ones. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.685)
Asymmetric-Information: Index ranging between one and seven and falling with the extent of information used 3.447 by buyers to make purchasing decisions. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.835)
Asset-Specificities: Index ranging between one and seven and gaging the competitive advantage of the 3.595 country’s companies in international markets. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (1.015)
Income: Natural logarithm of the output-side real GDP at chained PPPs in 2011 US dollar 9.213 per capita. Source: Penn World Table 9.0, available at https://pwt.sas.upenn.edu/ (1.194)
Democracy: Polity IV constraints on the executive authority score ranging between one and 5.303 seven. Source: POLITY IV dataset, available at http://www.systemicpeace.org (1.875)
Reserves: Crude oil proved reserves in barrels per capita. Source: Energy Information 1895.327
Other Administration, available at http://www.eia.gov/ (9400.035) controls:
Conflict-External: Share of previous half-century in which the country was involved in external 0.014 military conflicts. Source: http://www.correlatesofwar.org/ (0.050)
Conflict-Internal: Share of previous half-century in which the country was involved in internal 0.064 military conflicts. Source: http://www.correlatesofwar.org/ (0.120)
Human-Capital: Ratio of total tertiary enrollment, regardless of age, to the population of the relative 33.758 age group. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (25.843)
Technology-Availability: Index ranging between one and seven and gaging the availability of the latest 4.634
Excluded technologies. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (1.033) instruments:
Math-Science: Index ranging between one and seven and gaging the quality of math and science 3.943 education. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.975)
Note: 1. The last column reports the mean value and, in parentheses, the standard deviation of each variable. Both are computed for the 1350 observations used in tables 2 to 6.
35
Figure 1: Strength of Property Rights Protection
Note: 1. Here, I divide the range of each of the four variables, whose definitions and sources are listed in table 2, into four equal intervals.
36
Figure 2: Property Rights and Financial Inefficiencies
Note: 1. Residuals and fitted values lines are obtained from the sample employed in table 3.
Figure 3: Property Rights and Market Power
Note: 1. Residuals and fitted values lines are obtained from the sample employed in table 3.
Figure 4: Property Rights and Lemons-type Distortions
Note: 1. Residuals and fitted values lines are obtained from the sample employed in table 3.
37
Figure 5: Downstream Firm’s Property Rights and Incomplete Contracting Costs
Note: 1. Residuals and fitted values lines are obtained from the sample employed in table 3.
Figure 6: Property Rights and Transaction Costs
38
Table 3: Property Rights and Transaction Costs (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Panel A. The dependent variable is Property-Rights
Over-Regulation – 0.445 (0.049)***
Unavailability-Financing – 0.190 (0.078)**
Market-Dominance – 0.370 (0.061)***
Trade-Barriers – 0.238 (0.047)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.314 (0.044)***
Asset-Specificities 0.290 (0.059)***
Estimation OLS
R2 0.40 0.28 0.37 0.31 0.36 0.29 Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel B. The dependent variable is Intellectual-Property
Over-Regulation – 0.495 (0.063)***
Unavailability-Financing – 0.161 (0.080)**
Market-Dominance – 0.470 (0.065)***
Trade-Barriers – 0.181 (0.054)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.425 (0.053)***
Asset-Specificities 0.492 (0.078)***
Estimation OLS
R2 0.24 0.06 0.26 0.07 0.25 0.18 Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel C. The dependent variable is Shareholders-Protection
Over-Regulation – 0.337 (0.060)***
Unavailability-Financing – 0.243 (0.102)**
Market-Dominance – 0.356 (0.067)***
Trade-Barriers – 0.329 (0.052)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.317 (0.056)***
Asset-Specificities 0.367 (0.071)***
Estimation OLS
R2 0.25 0.23 0.28 0.28 0.28 0.24 Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Notes: 1. Robust standard errors allowing for clustering by country in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% confidence level; **, 5%; *, 10%. 2. All specifications include fixed country and year effects.
Table 4: Property Rights and Transaction Costs — Controlling for Observables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Panel A. The dependent variable is Property-Rights
Over-Regulation – 0.442 (0.049)***
Unavailability-Financing – 0.202 (0.071)***
Market-Dominance – 0.357 (0.061)***
Trade-Barriers – 0.226 (0.049)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.307 (0.048)***
Asset-Specificities 0.272 (0.058)***
P-value for all extra controls 0.08 0.07 0.33 0.31 0.56 0.27 Estimation OLS
R2 0.42 0.31 0.38 0.32 0.37 0.31 Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel B. The dependent variable is Intellectual-Property
Over-Regulation – 0.482 (0.063)***
Unavailability-Financing – 0.163 (0.077)**
Market-Dominance – 0.460 (0.065)***
Trade-Barriers – 0.174 (0.055)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.414 (0.055)***
Asset-Specificities 0.469 (0.078)***
P-value for all extra controls 0.04 0.10 0.08 0.14 0.56 0.17 Estimation OLS
R2 0.26 0.10 0.28 0.11 0.26 0.20 Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel C. The dependent variable is Shareholders-Protection
Over-Regulation – 0.340 (0.059)***
Unavailability-Financing – 0.268 (0.108)**
Market-Dominance – 0.357 (0.063)***
Trade-Barriers – 0.340 (0.053)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.329 (0.055)***
Asset-Specificities 0.352 (0.068)***
P-value for all extra controls 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.04 0.01 0.11 Estimation OLS
R2 0.27 0.25 0.30 0.30 0.30 0.25 Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Notes: 1. Robust standard errors allowing for clustering by country in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% confidence level; **, 5%; *, 10%. 2. All specifications include fixed country and year effects, Income, Democracy, Reserves, Conflict-External, Conflict-Internal, and Human-Capital.
39
Table 5: Using Selection on Observables to Assess the Bias from Unobservables (1) (2) (3)
The dependent variable is Property-Rights Intellectual-Property Shareholders-Protection
The measure of transaction cost is:
Over-Regulation 147.33 37.08 113.33
Unavailability-Financing 16.83 81.50 10.72
Market-Dominance 27.46 46 357
Trade-Barriers 18.83 24.86 30.91
Asymmetric-Information 43.86 37.64 27.42
Asset-Specificities 15.11 20.39 23.47
Note: 1. Each cell reports an index constructed as explained in section 4.1.2 and based on the coefficients attached to the measure of transaction costs listed on the left and obtained from two regressions. In one, the covariates include only fixed country and year effects. In the other, the “full set” of covariates gathers fixed country and year effects, Income, Democracy, Reserves, Conflict-External, Conflict-Internal, and Human-Capital. The number of observations is 1350.
Table 6: Property Rights and Endogenous Transaction Costs (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Panel A. The dependent variable is Property-Rights
Over-Regulation – 0.945 (0.166)***
Unavailability-Financing – 1.625 (0.396)***
Market-Dominance – 0.219 (0.047)***
Trade-Barriers – 1.185 (0.271)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.776 (0.122)***
Asset-Specificities 2.043 (0.647)***
P-value for all extra controls 0.00 0.17 0.67 0.35 0.18 0.79 First Stage for the Transaction Costs Measure
Technology-Availability – 0.139 – 0.112 – 0.219 – 0.168 – 0.100 0.023 (0.051)*** (0.038)*** (0.047)*** (0.049)*** (0.055)* (0.034)
Math-Science – 0.294 – 0.126 – 0.379 – 0.137 – 0.411 0.162 (0.053)*** (0.057)** (0.058)*** (0.074)* (0.062)*** (0.051)***
P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 P-value of overidentification test 0.49 0.15 0.24 0.07 0.65 0.46 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel B. The dependent variable is Intellectual-Property
Over-Regulation – 1.342 (0.206)***
Unavailability-Financing – 2.344 (0.613)***
Market-Dominance – 0.971 (0.103)***
Trade-Barriers – 1.725 (0.403)***
Asymmetric-Information – 1.088 (0.137)***
Asset-Specificities 2.846 (0.774)***
P-value for all extra controls 0.05 0.33 0.15 0.14 0.21 0.67 P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 P-value of overidentification test 0.81 0.24 0.37 0.16 0.30 0.23 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel C. The dependent variable is Shareholders-Protection
Over-Regulation – 0.630 (0.163)***
Unavailability-Financing – 1.182 (0.296)***
Market-Dominance – 0.466 (0.108)***
Trade-Barriers – 0.902 (0.232)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.481 (0.128)***
Asset-Specificities 1.217 (0.467)***
P-value for all extra controls 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.62 P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 P-value of overidentification test 0.29 0.86 0.41 0.79 0.08 0.05 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Notes: 1. Robust standard errors allowing for clustering by country in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% confidence level; **, 5%; *, 10%. 2. All specifications include fixed country and year effects, Income, Democracy, Reserves, Conflict-External, Conflict-Internal, and Human-Capital. The
endogenous variable in columns (1) to (6) is respectively Over-Regulation, Unavailability-Financing, Market-Dominance, Trade-Barriers, Asymmetric- Information, and Asset-Specificities, whereas the excluded instruments are Technology-Availability and Math-Science.
3. The null hypothesis of the Kleibergen-Paap test is that the excluded instruments are uncorrelated with the endogenous regressor. 4. The null hypothesis of the Hansen test of overidentifying restrictions is that the excluded instruments, as a group, are exogenous.
40
APPENDIX (NOT FOR PUBLICATION)
References
Dari-Mattiacci, Giuseppe, and Carmine Guerriero. 2017. “A Novel Dataset on Horizontal
Property Rights in 126 Jurisdictions.” Data in Brief, 11: 557-561.
Supplementary Tables
Table I: Summary of Variables Variable Definition and Sources Statistics
Property Years needed for adverse possession by any good-faith possessor of a movable good. 9.066 rights: Adverse-Possession: Source: Dari-Mattiacci and Guerriero (2017). (10.570)
[53] Index ranging between one and seven and rising with the extent to which making 2.902
Bribery: bribes in connection with their daily activities is common for firms. Source: 2006- (1.198) 2015 EOS. [1350] Index ranging between one and seven and rising with the difficulty to obtain a bank 3.995
Unavailability-Loans: loan with only a good business plan and no collateral. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.874) [1350]
Index ranging between one and seven and rising with how difficult is it for companies 3.254 Transaction Unavailability-Equity: to raise money by issuing shares on the stock market. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (1.105) costs: [1350]
Index ranging between one and seven and falling with the intensity of competition 2.165 Market-Power : in the local markets. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. (0.667)
[1350] Index ranging between one and seven and gaging the extent of production 3.792
Production-Sophistication: sophistication. A value of one (seven) suggests that production uses labor-intensive (1.064) (sophisticated and knowledge-intensive) processes. Source: 2006-2015 EOS. [1350] See text. Source: United Nations, Surveys of Crime Trends and the Operations of – 0.007
Enforcement: Criminal Justice Systems 2005-2015, available at https://www.unodc.org/ (1.012) Other [740] controls: See text. Sources: European Value Study and World Value Survey available at – 0.0004
Culture: http://www.europeanvaluesstudy.eu/ and http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/ (1.030) [590]
Note: 1. The last column reports the mean value and, in parentheses, the standard deviation of each variable. Both are computed for the 1350 observations used in tables III to V, except in the case of Adverse-Possession for which they are calculated for the 91 observations employed in table II.
41
Table II: Property Rights and Endogenous Transaction Costs — Cross-Section (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Panel A. The dependent variable is Adverse-Possession
Over-Regulation – 14.204 (4.986)***
Unavailability-Financing – 6.370 (3.149)**
Market-Dominance – 11.314 (4.060)***
Trade-Barriers – 11.827 (6.805)*
Asymmetric-Information – 15.717 (6.552)**
Asset-Specificities 8.742 (2.988)***
P-value of underidentification test 0.20 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 P-value of overidentification test 0.82 0.19 0.81 0.21 0.82 0.97 P-value of endogeneity test 0.08 0.02 0.11 0.15 0.06 0.06 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 53 53 53 53 53 53
Panel B. The dependent variable is Property-Rights
Over-Regulation – 1.880 (0.639)***
Unavailability-Financing – 1.135 (0.252)***
Market-Dominance – 1.514 (0.411)***
Trade-Barriers – 2.088 (0.722)***
Asymmetric-Information – 2.108 (0.705)***
Asset-Specificities 1.126 (0.277)***
P-value of underidentification test 0.20 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 P-value of overidentification test 0.17 0.32 0.18 0.40 0.14 0.09 P-value of endogeneity test 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 53 53 53 53 53 53
Panel C. The dependent variable is Intellectual-Property
Over-Regulation – 2.297 (0.878)***
Unavailability-Financing – 1.232 (0.265)***
Market-Dominance – 1.841 (0.382)***
Trade-Barriers – 2.273 (0.827)***
Asymmetric-Information – 2.561 (0.717)***
Asset-Specificities 1.392 (0.288)***
P-value of underidentification test 0.20 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 P-value of overidentification test 0.57 0.07 0.45 0.18 0.56 0.20 P-value of endogeneity test 0.00 0.13 0.00 0.09 0.00 0.01 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 53 53 53 53 53 53
Panel D. The dependent variable is Shareholders-Protection
Over-Regulation – 1.465 (0.682)**
Unavailability-Financing – 0.959 (0.141)***
Market-Dominance – 1.184 (0.267)***
Trade-Barriers – 1.761 (0.543)***
Asymmetric-Information – 1.650 (0.411)***
Asset-Specificities 0.870 (0.273)***
P-value of underidentification test 0.20 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 P-value of overidentification test 0.11 0.45 0.08 0.65 0.03 0.04 P-value of endogeneity test 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.00 0.06 0.05 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 53 53 53 53 53 53
Notes: 1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% confidence level; **, 5%; *, 10%. 2. All specifications include Income, Democracy, Reserves, Conflict-External, Conflict-Internal, Human-Capital, Enforcement, and Culture. The en-
dogenous variable in columns (1) to (6) is respectively Over-Regulation, Unavailability-Financing, Market-Dominance, Trade-Barriers, Asymmetric- Information, and Asset-Specificities, whereas the excluded instruments are Technology-Availability and Math-Science.
3. The null hypothesis of the Kleibergen-Paap test is that the excluded instruments are uncorrelated with the endogenous regressor. 4. The null hypothesis of the Hansen test of overidentifying restrictions is that the excluded instruments, as a group, are exogenous. 5. The null hypothesis of the endogeneity test is that the endogenous regressor can be treated as exogenous.
42
Table III: Property Rights and Other Measures of Endogenous Transaction Costs (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Panel A. The dependent variable is Adverse-Possession
Bribery – 1.427 (0.321)***
Unavailability-Loans – 0.763 (0.141)***
Unavailability-Equity – 0.617 (0.175)***
Market-Power – 0.622 (0.144)***
Production-Sophistication 0.817 (0.127)***
P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 P-value of overidentification test 0.60 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.53 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel B. The dependent variable is Intellectual-Property
Bribery – 2.027 (0.454)***
Unavailability-Loans – 1.051 (0.174)***
Unavailability-Equity – 0.802 (0.202)***
Market-Power – 0.937 (0.173)***
Production-Sophistication 1.159 (0.123)***
P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 P-value of overidentification test 0.82 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.81 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel C. The dependent variable is Shareholders-Protection
Bribery – 0.953 (0.258)***
Unavailability-Loans – 0.422 (0.135)***
Unavailability-Equity – 0.216 (0.164)
Market-Power – 0.557 (0.154)***
Production-Sophistication 0.543 (0.139)***
P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 P-value of overidentification test 0.28 0.01 0.00 0.08 0.28 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Notes: 1. Robust standard errors allowing for clustering by country in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% confidence level; **, 5%; *, 10%. 2. All specifications include fixed country and year effects, Income, Democracy, Reserves, Conflict-External, Conflict-Internal, and Human-Capital.
The endogenous variables in columns (1) to (5) is respectively Bribery, Unavailability-Loans, Unavailability-Equity, Market-Power, and Production- Sophistication, whereas the excluded instruments are Technology-Availability and Math-Science.
3. The null hypothesis of the Kleibergen-Paap test is that the excluded instruments are uncorrelated with the endogenous regressor. 4. The null hypothesis of the Hansen test of overidentifying restrictions is that the excluded instruments, as a group, are exogenous.
Table IV: Controlling for the Intermediation Technology (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Panel A. The dependent variable is Property-Rights
Over-Regulation – 0.906 (0.376)**
Unavailability-Financing – 1.591 (0.454)***
Market-Dominance – 1.013 (0.293)***
Trade-Barriers – 1.340 (0.610)**
Asymmetric-Information – 0.753 (0.307)**
Asset-Specificities – 8.719 (16.529)
P-value of underidentification test 0.06 0.07 0.04 0.06 0.10 0.86 P-value of overidentification test 0.11 0.29 0.02 0.83 0.06 0.81 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 310 310 310 310 310 310
Panel B. The dependent variable is Intellectual-Property
Over-Regulation – 1.452 (0.401)***
Unavailability-Financing – 2.150 (0.600)***
Market-Dominance – 1.665 (0.417)***
Trade-Barriers – 1.891 (0.780)**
Asymmetric-Information – 1.291 (0.423)***
Asset-Specificities – 14.025 (27.297)
P-value of underidentification test 0.06 0.07 0.04 0.06 0.10 0.86 P-value of overidentification test 0.26 0.12 0.07 0.68 0.06 0.88 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 310 310 310 310 310 310
Panel C. The dependent variable is Shareholders-Protection
Over-Regulation – 0.620 (0.393)
Unavailability-Financing – 1.681 (0.487)***
Market-Dominance – 0.635 (0.438)
Trade-Barriers – 1.298 (0.479)***
Asymmetric-Information – 0.391 (0.421)
Asset-Specificities – 5.901 (11.821)
P-value of underidentification test 0.06 0.07 0.04 0.06 0.10 0.86 P-value of overidentification test 0.07 0.93 0.03 0.65 0.04 0.60 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 310 310 310 310 310 310
Notes: 1. Robust standard errors allowing for clustering by country in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% confidence level; **, 5%; *, 10%. 2. All specifications include fixed country and year effects, Income, Democracy, Reserves, Conflict-External, Conflict-Internal, Human-Capital, Enforce-
ment, and Culture. The endogenous variable in columns (1) to (6) is respectively Over-Regulation, Unavailability-Financing, Market-Dominance, Trade-Barriers, Asymmetric-Information, and Asset-Specificities, whereas the excluded instruments are Technology-Availability and Math-Science.
3. The null hypothesis of the Kleibergen-Paap test is that the excluded instruments are uncorrelated with the endogenous regressor. 4. The null hypothesis of the Hansen test of overidentifying restrictions is that the excluded instruments, as a group, are exogenous.
43
Table V: Property Rights and Endogenous Transaction Costs — Semi-reduced Forms (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Panel A. The dependent variable is Property-Rights
Over-Regulation – 1.031 (0.200)***
Unavailability-Financing – 2.403 (1.008)**
Market-Dominance – 0.800 (0.125)***
Trade-Barriers – 2.212 (1.127)**
Asymmetric-Information – 0.738 (0.140)***
Asset-Specificities 1.870 (0.601)***
Technology-Availability – 0.041 – 0.168 – 0.073 – 0.269 0.029 0.059 (0.062) (0.156) (0.064) (0.254) (0.062) (0.075)
P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.00 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel B. The dependent variable is Intellectual-Property
Over-Regulation – 1.383 (0.253)***
Unavailability-Financing – 3.224 (1.433)**
Market-Dominance – 1.073 (0.161)***
Trade-Barriers – 2.967 (1.669)*
Asymmetric-Information – 0.990 (0.142)***
Asset-Specificities 2.508 (0.707)***
Technology-Availability – 0.020 – 0.190 – 0.062 – 0.326 0.074 0.114 (0.085) (0.210) (0.073) (0.367) (0.067) (0.084)
P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.00 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel C. The dependent variable is Shareholders-Protection
Over-Regulation – 0.474 (0.219)**
Unavailability-Financing – 1.104 (0.570)**
Market-Dominance – 0.368 (0.160)**
Trade-Barriers – 1.017 (0.520)**
Asymmetric-Information – 0.339 (0.152)**
Asset-Specificities 0.859 (0.417)**
Technology-Availability 0.075 0.017 0.060 – 0.030 0.107 0.121 (0.069) (0.096) (0.072) (0.122) (0.059)* (0.056)**
P-value of underidentification test 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.07 0.00 0.00 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel D. The dependent variable is Property-Rights
Over-Regulation – 0.735 (0.331)**
Unavailability-Financing – 0.909 (0.430)**
Market-Dominance – 0.467 (0.203)**
Trade-Barriers – 0.609 (0.301)**
Asymmetric-Information – 1.024 (0.660)
Asset-Specificities 4.388 (6.399)
Technology-Availability 0.087 0.189 0.126 0.220 – 0.117 – 0.409 (0.115) (0.092)** (0.100) (0.081)*** (0.299) (1.067)
P-value of underidentification test 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.07 0.49 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel E. The dependent variable is Intellectual-Property
Over-Regulation – 1.241 (0.470)***
Unavailability-Financing – 1.535 (0.570)***
Market-Dominance – 0.788 (0.213)***
Trade-Barriers – 1.028 (0.399)***
Asymmetric-Information – 1.729 (0.930)*
Asset-Specificities 7.409 (10.093)
Technology-Availability 0.042 0.213 0.108 0.266 – 0.303 – 0.795 (0.166) (0.127)* (0.110) (0.127)** (0.414) (1.707)
P-value of underidentification test 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.07 0.49 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Panel F. The dependent variable is Shareholders-Protection
Over-Regulation – 1.012 (0.453)**
Unavailability-Financing – 1.253 (0.470)***
Market-Dominance – 0.643 (0.249)***
Trade-Barriers – 0.838 (0.338)**
Asymmetric-Information – 1.410 (0.813)*
Asset-Specificities 6.045 (8.391)
Technology-Availability – 0.158 – 0.019 – 0.105 0.024 – 0.440 – 0.841 (0.169) (0.112) (0.129) (0.091) (0.365) (1.395)
P-value of underidentification test 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.07 0.49 Estimation 2SLS Number of observations 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350 1350
Notes: 1. Robust standard errors allowing for clustering by country in parentheses. *** significant at the 1% confidence level; **, 5%; *, 10%. 2. All specifications include fixed country and year effects, Income, Democracy, Reserves, Conflict-External, Conflict-Internal, and Human-Capital. The
endogenous variables in columns (1) to (6) is respectively Over-Regulation, Unavailability-Financing, Market-Dominance, Trade-Barriers, Asymmetric- Information, and Asset-Specificities, whereas the excluded instruments are Math-Science in panels A to C and Technology-Availability otherwise.
3. The null hypothesis of the Kleibergen-Paap test is that the excluded instruments are uncorrelated with the endogenous regressor.
44
"Is this question part of your assignment? We Can Help!"
